METSÄNTUTKIMUSLAITOKSEN TIEDONANTOJA 708, 1998 FINNISH FOREST RESEARCH INSTITUTE, RESEARCH PAPERS 708, 1998 Demand for Finnish exports of forest products: Econometric analyses using time series data Riitta Hänninen HELSINGIN TUTKIMUSKESKUS - HELSINKI RESEARCH CENTRE METSÄNTUTKIMUSLAITOKSEN TIEDONANTOJA 708,1998 FINNISH FOREST RESEARCH INSTITUTE, RESEARCH PAPERS, 708, 1998 DEMAND FOR FINNISH EXPORTS OF FOREST PRODUCTS: Econometric analyses using time series data Riitta Hänninen Doctoral dissertation To be presented, by the permission of the Faculty of Agriculture and Forestry of the University of Helsinki, for public examination in Auditorium XII of the main building of the University, Unioninkatu 34, on November 13, 1998 at 12 o'clock noon. HELSINGIN TUTKIMUSKESKUS - HELSINKI RESEARCH CENTRE Hänninen, Riitta. 1998. Demand for Finnish exports of forest products: Econometric analyses using time series data. Metsäntutkimuslaitoksen tiedonantoja 708. Finnish Forest Research Institute, Research papers 708. ISBN 951-40 -1650 -5, ISSN 0358 - 4283. 60 p. + 5 original papers. Publisher: Finnish Forest Research Institute Approved: Matti Kärkkäinen, Research Director, 25.9.1998 Author's address: Riitta Hänninen, Finnish Forest Research Institute, Helsinki Research Center, Unioninkatu 40 A, 00170 Helsinki, Finland, tel: +358 9 857057 46, fax: +358 9 85705717 e-mail: riitta.hanninen@metla.fi Doctoral dissertation at the Department of Forest Economics, University of Helsinki Supervised by: Professor Jari Kuuluvainen, Department of Forest Economics, University of Helsinki Pre-examiners: Ph. D. Jussi Uusi vuori Finnish Forest Research Institute Helsinki and Dr. Jouko Vilmunen Research Department, Bank of Finland Helsinki Opponent: Professor Joseph Buongiorno Forest Ecology and Management, University of Wisconsin Madison, USA ABSTRACT The study analyses Finland's and its main competitor countries' export price formation in British (UK) and German (BDR) forest product markets using time series data. The results of the study are useful in modeling forest product trade flows. They also yield information for policy makers and industrial agents, for example, in the adjustment to the third stage of European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU). Johansen's cointegration method, thusfar infreaqvently applied to the Finnish forest sector, is used in the estimation. Export price formation is examined in three ways. First, price substitution between Finland's, and its competitor's sawnwood is analysed in the UK market. Second, the law of one price (LOP) related to arbitrage is tested for prices of sawnwood and newsprint originating from Finland, and its competitor countries. Finally, the effects of exchange rate changes on Finnish sawnwood, newsprint and chemical pulp export prices are analysed in both destination countries. The estimation results indicated imperfect competition in the export markets. The price elasticities of substitution between Finnish, Swedish and Canadian sawnwoods were relatively low and the LOP was rejected in the UK. The LOP was also rejected between the main newsprint supplying countries in German and British markets except between Sweden and Canada in the UK. The resulting exchange rate pass-through (PT) elasticities of Finnish export prices indicate the importance of exchange rates on exports of forest products. Higher PT for sawnwood than for paper suggests that Finnish sawnwood exporters have made use of depreciations and devaluations of the Finnish markka (FIM) to improve their price competitiveness and to maintain and increase market share. In paper markets, Finnish exporters have pursued a midway pricing strategy aimed at both maintaining market shares and profitability. Key words: Forest products, sawnwood, newsprint, export price formation, imperfect competition, elasticity of substitution, law of one price, exchange rate pass-through, Johansen cointegration method, United Kingdom, Germany Dedicated to my son Tapio Preface My research interest on price determination and exchange rate effects on Finnish exports of forest products is related to Finland's participation in the integration of Europe. The realization of European Monetary Union (EMU) on 1.1.1999 is the next step in this process and it will intensely affect the market environment for Finnish forest industry. Although it is difficult to asses the future by analysing historical data, the results of the present study give insights into operating within the impending EMU. The present study is part of the project "Short-term Forecasting System for the Finnish Forest Sector" (MESU) at the Finnish Forest Research Institute (Metla) between 1994 and 1998. The research has been mainly financed by Metla, but research grants from Metsämiesten Säätiö are also gratefully acknowledged. My special gratitude belongs to Jari Kuuluvainen, who has supervised my work from the beginning with encouragement and guidance. Moreover, as my previous project leader and collaborator, Jari has been an essential support throughout all of my scientific work. I also want to thank Heikki Juslin for his encouragement of my studies and Mikko Tervo for his comments on this summarizing report. My project leader, Lauri Hetemäki, has been important throughout my research and his constructive criticism has greatly increased my skills as a researcher. I am also grateful to Anne Toppinen for her friendship and her participation in this project, as well as her collaboration on other projects. Part of this dissertation is a result from joint research with Anne as well as Pertti Ruuska. Antti Ripatti helped me with methodological questions and the comments of both Ville Ovaskainen and Ashley Selby were also helpful in organizing this summarizing report. I also want to thank, warmly, my pre-examiners, Jussi Uusivuori and Jouko Vilmunen, for their valuable comments and suggestions to improve the summary report. Additionally, Robert Craig has been helpful in improving my English in the final stages of the summary report. I have been fortunate to share a researcher's life with my beloved husband, Harri, to whom I am profoundly grateful for his support and understanding. Kerava, October 9, 1998 Riitta Hänninen LIST OF SEPARATE STUDIES 10 1. INTRODUCTION 11 1.1. Background and justification 11 1.2 Aim and outline 13 2. EXPORTERS' MARKET SHARES AND UNIT PRICES IN THE UK AND GERMANY 15 3. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND EARLIER LITERATURE 20 3.1 Trade models and market competition 20 3.2. Modeling export markets using Armington approach 22 3.3 Testing the law of one price in forest products markets 25 3.4 Exchange rate pass-through on forest products export prices 28 4. DATA 32 5. COINTEGRATION METHOD 35 51. Johansen's multivariate cointegration method 35 52. Testable hypotheses 39 6. RESULTS 43 6.1 Price elasticities of substitution between Finland and the other supplier countries in the demand of the United Kingdom sawnwood imports 43 6.2 The law of one price in United Kingdom soft sawnwood imports - a cointegration approach 44 6.3 Testing arbitrage in newsprint imports to United Kingdom and Germany 45 6.4 Exchange rate changes and the Finnish sawnwood demand and price in the UK market 46 6.5 Long-run price effects of exchange rate changes on Finnish pulp and paper exports 47 7. CONCLUSIONS 48 REFERENCES 51 10 LIST OF SEPARATE STUDIES The dissertation includes the following separate studies: Hänninen, R. 1994. Price elasticities of substitution between Finland and the other supplier countries in the demand of the United Kingdom sawnwood imports. In Proceedings of the Biennial meeting of the Scandinavian Forest Economics, Helles, F., and Linddal, M. (eds.). Scandinavian Forest Economics 35:204-217. Hänninen, R., Toppinen, A., and Ruuska, P. 1997. Testing arbitrage in newsprint imports to United Kingdom and Germany. Canadian Journal of Forest Research 27:1946-1952. Hänninen, R. H. 1998 a. The law of one price in United Kingdom soft sawnwood imports - a cointegration approach. Forest Science 44(1): 17-23 Hänninen, R. H. 1998b. Exchange rate changes and the Finnish sawnwood demand and price in the UK market. Silva Fennica 32(l):61-73. Hänninen, R. and Toppinen, A. 1998. Long-run price effects of exchange rate changes in Finnish pulp and paper exports. Forthcoming in Applied Economics. The first four articles are reprinted with permission. 11 1. INTRODUCTION 1.1. Background and justification Substantial changes in the export market environment produce challenges for Finnish forest industry. Competition in world markets and Finland's main market area, Europe, is likely to increase in the future due to new producers and low production costs in, e.g., Southeast Asia (Hetemäki* 1997). The realization of the third phase of European Economic and Monetary Union (EMU) on 1.1.1999 removes the exchange rate buffer for Finnish forest industry trade with the other EMU countries. Adjustment difficulties to the new market environment may arise, if exchange rate has an important effect on Finnish exports. A common currency will facilitate price comparisons in the EMU area, which may increase competition between producers in different countries. This study produces information about price formation and competition in export markets, which is useful for policy makers and for industry in adjusting to future market changes. For those modeling Finnish forest industry exports, the information is also useful in choosing a suitable modeling strategy. The study focuses on the two most important export countries for Finland in the European Union, the United Kingdom (UK) and Germany (BDR). They accounted for 32 percent of sawnwood exports, 42 percent of newsprint exports and 60 percent of chemical pulp exports from Finland in 1996 (Statistical Yearbook... 1997). Finnish sawnwood and newsprint industries are clearly export industries; the greatest part of their production is exported. In the Finnish chemical pulp industry, the export share of total production is, however, only about 25 percent. Finland's main competitors in paper and pulp markets are Sweden, Canada and the USA, and in sawnwood markets Sweden, Canada and Russia. Sawnwood, newsprint and chemical pulp were chosen for this analysis, because they form relatively homogenous product groups, a prerequisite for an analysis based on unit prices. In the present study of price formation three different aspects are examined. First, the study examines price substitution. Second, it tests the existence of price differences (the law of one price, LOP) between Finland's and its competitor's products. Third, the magnitude of exchange rate changes on Finnish export demand and prices expressed in terms of foreign 12 currency (pass-through effect) is examined. The three topics have implications as to the degree of competition in the market. High substitution elasticities, the existence of LOP and a low pass-through (PT) effect would imply perfectly competitive markets, whereas, relatively low substitution elasticities, the rejection of the LOP and a high PT would indicate imperfect competition. Previous studies on export price formation in the whole of Finnish industry suggest imperfect competition at the aggregate level (Honkatukia 1994). For paper industry exports, the results gave clear support to a judgement of imperfect competition, but for wood products the evidence was less clear-cut (Sukselainen 1986, Honkatukia 1994 and 1995). Because forest industry produces many different products and product groups, it is natural that each of these may show varying degrees of competition in export markets. Thus, it is difficult to obtain a uniform view over the degree of competition in their international trade. Traded products may be relatively homogenous, suggesting more perfect than imperfect competition. However, even in this case market imperfections remain possible. Studies modeling the trade in different forest products have used different assumptions concerning competition. In some studies the starting point has been perfect competition, while the others assume imperfect competition. The assumptions are not, however, usually explicitly tested. In particular, the differences between Finland's and its competitor's prices have not been statistically tested in earlier works, although there do exist a few studies on the effect of exchange rate on Finnish forest product exports (e.g. Uusivuori and Buongiorno 1990, Vesala 1992, Laaksonen 1998). In the estimation of exchange rate effects, the present study uses Johansen's method (1988), which takes account of time series properties and cointegration of the data. This has been done only in the most recent studies of the Finnish forest sector (e.g., Ripatti 1990, Toppinen and Kuuluvainen 1997, Laaksonen 1998, and Toppinen 1998). Using new estimation methods, additional information is generated on export price formation, thus increasing the understanding of the functioning of forest products export markets. 13 1.2 Aim and outline The study examines forest products price formation in Finnish export markets by applying partial equilibrium models and the econometric method. The analysis includes five separate studies concerning soft sawnwood, newsprint and chemical pulp exports to Finland's most important export countries, the United Kingdom and Germany. The analysis can be divided into three specific sub-topics: 1. Price substitution in the UK sawnwood imports from Finland, Sweden, Canada and Russia (Hänninen 1994). 2. The existence of long-term price differences in UK sawnwood imports and in British and German newsprint imports from major suppliers (Hänninen 1998 a, Hänninen et ai. 1997). 3. Exchange rate effects on Finnish sawnwood export demand and price in the UK market and on Finnish newsprint and chemical pulp prices in the UK and Germany (Hänninen 1998b, Hänninen and Toppinen 1998). The study of the first topic aimed to estimate own-price and substitution elasticities between the four supplier countries' sawnwoods in the UK market. For this purpose, an econometric model for UK sawnwood demand from the supplier countries generalizing the original export demand model of Armington (1969) was specified and estimated using annual data from the period 1961-1990. The studies of the second topic examined differences between Finland's, and its competitor's export prices for sawnwood and newsprint in the UK and Germany. The analyses were done by testing the law of one price (LOP) in these markets using quarterly data from the period 1978-1992 for sawnwood and 1980-1994 for newsprint. The studies of the third topic aimed to examine the effects of exchange rate changes on Finnish sawnwood, newsprint and chemical pulp export prices. For newsprint and pulp exchange rate PT was estimated from a markup price equation (e.g., Hung et al. 1993) and for sawnwood, the model was enlarged to include an export demand equation assuming constant elasticity of substitution between supplier countries. The estimations were made using quarterly data from the period 1978-1994 for sawnwood and 1980-1994 for newsprint. 14 The outline of the present summary paper is as follows. Chapter 2 presents the development of Finland's and its competitor's market shares and the prices of their exports in the UK and Germany. Chapter 3 reviews the related literature and presents the theoretical framework of the studies. Data is summarized in Chapter 4 and Johansen's cointegration method and the testable hypothesis of the study are presented in Chapter 5. Short summaries of each study are presented in Chapter 6 followed by conclusions with suggestions for further research in Chapter 7. 15 2. EXPORTERS' MARKET SHARES AND UNIT PRICES IN THE UK AND GERMANY The main exporters to the UK sawnwood market, Finland, Sweden, Canada and Russia, account for about 80 percent of total UK sawnwood imports. The UK is highly dependent on imports, even though it doubled domestic sawnwood production between 1980 and 1994. The percentage ratio share of domestic production to imports has increased during the past 14 years from 18 percent in 1980 to 25 percent in 1994 (FAO 1991 and 1994). In the newsprint markets of the UK and Germany, the main suppliers are Finland, Sweden and Canada. These three countries account for about 85 per cent of newsprint imports into the UK and 68 percent into Germany. Both countries have doubled their newsprint production between 1980 and 1994 and increased the percentage ratio of domestic production to imports. In 1980 the ratio was 34 percent in the UK and 70 percent in Germany. In 1994, the respective ratios were 45 percent and 116 percent. (FAO 1991 and 1994). The UK is far more dependent on imported newsprint than Germany. The import shares' of suppliers show relatively large business fluctuations in UK sawnwood and newsprint imports over time, while in Germany, market shares have been rather stable (Figures 1-2). The market shares of suppliers (see Table 1 in: Hänninen 1998 a and Hänninen et ai. 1997) have also been relatively similar indicating that the supplier countries have not differed much from each other in terms of their potential market power. The main events in the UK sawnwood market were the decrease of the Russian share after the collapse of the Soviet Union and large fluctuations in the Canadian and Swedish shares (Figure 1). Finland's share, however, has been rather stable. In UK newsprint imports, Finland has lost somewhat of its share, while Swedish market share has increased (Figure 2). The decline of the Finnish share in the UK has partially been offset by the acquisition of 1 Suppliers' percentage import shares are calculated by dividing the sawnwood and newsprint import quantity of each supplier by the respective total imports to the UK and Germany. The data for Figures land 2 are obtained from the British and German national customs statistics (CSO, Statistiches Bundesamt). 16 production capacity by Finnish forest industries in the UK market during the 1980 s. In the 19905, Finnish firms have also established newsprint production capacity in Germany. Figure 1. Supplier countries' percentage shares of total sawnwood imports into the United Kingdom, 1980-1994. Figure 2. Supplier countries' percentage shares of total newsprint imports into the United Kingdom and Germany, 1980-1994. 17 Supplier countries' export prices for newsprint and sawnwood are presented in Figures 3-4. If suppliers' prices in the eport markets differ, suppliers must have at least some market power. Figure 3. Logarithms of quarterly real unit prices of newsprint imports into the United Kingdom and Germany (GBP/metric ton and DEM/ton), 1980-1994. 18 From the graphs of the price series 2 , it could be concluded that the suppliers' real unit prices have developed, relatively uniformly, in newsprint markets. After a stable price development during the 1980 s, there has been a fall in real newsprint prices in both importing countries during the economic recession of the early 1990 s (Figure 3). Price development in the sawnwood market has been different. Graphs of real sawnwood prices reveal that, especially in the second half of the period, price series have clearly deviated from each other in the UK (Figure 4). Therefore, the LOP is more probably valid for newsprint than for sawnwood. However, explicit tests taking into account time series properties of the data are required to obtain statistically accurate information about the validity of the LOP. Figure 4. Logarithms of quarterly real unit prices of sawnwood imports to the United Kingdom (GBP/m 3 ), 1978-1992. 2 The time series of prices are suppliers' quarterly import unit values into the UK and Germany calculated by dividing the value (CIF, including cost, insurance and freight) of the suppliers' exports by the respective quantity. The sources of the data are British and German national customs statistics (CSO, Statistiches Bundesamt). Unit prices were deflated by the UK and German producer price indexes obtained from the Main Economic Indicators (OECD). More information on the data can be found in Hänninen 1998 a and Hänninen et ai. 1997. 19 Graphs of Finnish newsprint prices, and exchange rates with the destination countries (see Hänninen and Toppinen 1998: Figure 1) indicate that these series are negatively correlated with each other. This suggests some degree of exchange rate PT in both markets; FIM depreciations have lowered the price of exports from Finland and FIM appreciations have raised it. This also seems to hold for Finnish sawnwood exports (Hänninen 1998b: Figures 1C and ID). During the period studied, the FIM fluctuated widely with respect to GBP and Deutsche mark (DEM) (Hänninen and Toppinen 1998, Figure 1A). Moreover, the exchange rate regime was revised several times. During the period 1978-1991, the FIM was expressed with a currency basket index which was a trade weighted average of the exchange rates of Finland's most important trade partners. In 1984, the peg was changed when the Soviet currency was removed from the index. The currency basket index was supposed to be kept within a band or a target zone. Under this system the devaluations and revaluations were made by specific decision of Finnish government. The FIM was revalued in 1979, 1980, 1989 and devalued in 1978, 1982. In June 1991, the FIM was linked to ECU basket upon application of EU membership. However, as a result of speculative attacks the FIM was devalued in November 1991. During 1992, the FIM with several other European currencies came again under massive speculative attacks and the Bank of Finland decided to abandon the peg to ECU. In September 1992, the FIM was devalued and it was allowed to float until October 1996, when Finland decided to join the European Exchange Rate Mechanism (ERM). 20 3. THEORETICAL FRAMEWORK AND EARLIER LITERATURE 3.1 Trade models and market competition The traditional theory of foreign trade explains trade entirely with differences between countries, especially differences in their factor endowments. It assumes comparative advantage, perfectly competitive markets, homogeneity of goods and constant returns-to scale technology (e.g. Helpman and Krugman 1985). However, traditional trade theory cannot explain why industrial countries have large exports and imports of relatively similar products. In reality, many industries cannot be characterized by constant returns-to-scale. Modern approaches to trade theory explain that economies of scale (i.e., increasing returns to-scale) in industrial production technologies will lead countries to specialize in production and then trade with one another. It also assumes imperfect competition in the market. Large forest sector models are commonly based on the assumption of perfect competition 3 . For example, ETTS V presents forecasts for different countries' forest products exports and imports in this framework (Brooks et al. 1995). The Swedish forest sector model assumes perfect competition in West European markets (Byström and Eriksson 1991). The same assumption is also used in partial equilibrium model for the global forest sector, The General Trade Model, GTM, (Dykstra and Kallio 1987) and in the annual medium-term econometric model for the Finnish economy (KESSU) (Hetemäki and Kaski 1992). The quarterly model of Finnish economy (BOF4) assumes perfect competition for Finnish industry exports in the long-run, but imperfect competition in the short run (The BOF4, Quarterly Model... 1990). Perfect competition is also assumed in some small partial equilibrium models of trade in individual forest products. For example, Buongiorno and Gilless (1984), who modelled newsprint trade, Andersen (1993), who studied European newsprint markets, and Brännlund et al. (1982), who modeled Swedish exports of forest products to Western Europe, assumed perfect competition. 3 In a perfectly competitive market there are many buyers and sellers and none of them has a large market share. Sellers are price-takers and they can only adjust their quantity at the current world market price. Free entrance to the market and free exit also characterize the existence of perfect competition. 21 On the other hand, several other studies have assumed imperfect competition 4 . Some previous models of the newsprint industry in North America (e.g., Dagenais 1976, Booth et al. 1991) assumed oligopoly with dominant firm price leadership. Brännlund and Löfgren (1995) assumed that Canadian pulp and newsprint industry is a price setter in North America, but a quantity setter in its European exports. In the study of Wiberg (1987), Swedish pulp exports to Germany are assumed to follow price-setting behavior. Oligopoly was assumed by Halonen (1990), who studied Finnish and Swedish pulp and paper exports and Ronnila (1995), who analyzed Finnish paper exports and tested Cournot oligopoly in Europe. Overall, the results indicated the possibility of noncompetitive behavior in the Finnish paper industry. In a number of studies that have applied the theory of Armington (1969), imperfect competition is assumed in the trade of individual forest products. Imperfect competition was assumed, for example, in US softwood lumber imports from Canada (Hseu and Buongiorno 1993), in Finnish sawnwood exports to Europe (Hänninen 1986) and the UK (Tervo et al. 1988), in Finnish paper exports to the UK (e.g., Laaksonen et al. 1997) and in Finnish paper exports to the UK and Germany (Volk 1983). In sum, some previous studies of forest product exports have assumed perfect competition, while others have assumed imperfect competition. Forest product markets include many different products and product groups and each of these may show varying degrees of competition in different countries and in different time periods. Thus, it is difficult to obtain a uniform view as to the degree of competition in their international trade. Even though the traded products in question were homogenous, thus suggesting more perfect than imperfect competition, the existence of market imperfections remains a possibility. In forest industry, there are attributes that would suggest perfect competition. In pulp and paper industry, product standards and specifications are fairly universal, exporters' foreign investment in capacity has increased and mergers and acquisitions are common (e.g., 4 Imperfect market competition is usually characteristic of markets in which there are only a few major producers as well as markets, where each producer's product is seen by consumers as differentiated from those of rivals. In imperfect competition, each producer may be a price-setter, unlike in perfect competition. In imperfect competition, a producer faces a downward sloping demand curve indicating that the quantities sold increase when prices fall. 22 Canadian Forest Service 1996). In the sawnwood industry, the products of different suppliers are also relatively homogenous. However, there are also features suggesting market imperfections. The concentration development of forest industry, especially in the paper sector, does not necessarily promote competition. It has also been common to forest industry that firms voluntarily cut production to be able to maintain certain price levels, instead of competing on price (Ronnila 1995). In the paper industry, the investment costs of new plants are high, which is likely to deter new firms from entering the market. Also, exit from the market may be complicated. Due to the high investment costs, it is not easy to eliminate the excess capacity, if it exists. Exit from the market requires that high-priced production plants are sold to competitors. In sawnwood industry, imperfections in competition can be assumed to arise from regionally concentrated trade and differences in building codes, product dimensions and grades between countries (Canadian Forest Service 1996). According to Buongiorno et al. (1979, p. 643) systematic distortions are also possible in commodity markets in the case where products are technically relatively homogenous. For example, preferences for lumber quality, even of the same species and grade, business practices and habits as well as attachments to a particular supplier country or even to a specific supplier may differ depending on the importing country. These effects are related to switching costs that consumers or other end-users may face when switching between brands or suppliers of a product (e.g., Froot and Klemperer 1989). Okun (1975) stresses the costs of breaking personal sales relationships in industrial transactions. Supplying firms may create relationships with customers by, e.g., using repeat-purchase discounts or making services incompatible with those of other firms. 3.2. Modeling export markets using the Armington approach The traditional export demand theory of Armington (1969) assumes that products from different countries of origin are imperfect substitutes for each other. The model has been widely applied in studies of international trade of various commodities, for example, US 23 cotton exports (Babula 1987, Duffy et al. 1990), world trade in rice (Ito et al. 1990) and fruits and vegetables (Sarris 1983) and for Finland's foreign trade in services (Miikkulainen 1989). Armington's approach has been applied to the modeling of forest products trade by, e.g., Chou and Buongiorno (1983), who studied the US demand for plywood imports by country of origin. Blatner (1989) estimated the price elasticities for Western European countries' imports of paper products by supplier country. In Finnish studies, the model has been applied in modeling sawnwood exports to western European countries (Hänninen 1986), and to the UK market (Tervo et al. 1988) as well as in paper exports (Volk 1983 and Laaksonen et. al 1997). The popularity of the Armington model derives from the simplicity with which it estimates complicated substitutability relationships. The model assumes that the consumers' utility function is homogeneous of degree one in prices and weakly separable so that the consumer's decision process occurs in two stages. First, the total quantity of imports of a product is determined, and then second, the quantity to be imported is allocated among competing suppliers using constant elasticity of substitution (CES) demand functions. Weak separability in consumption (or production) has the advantage that it saves degrees of freedom in the estimation. This makes it possible to reduce the number of variables in the analysis. It is an essential advantage in models of international trade that invariably concern many commodities and several exporting and importing countries. Too many commodities in the consumption function and too many separate inputs in the production function would not lead to a meaningful statistical analysis. The restrictive assumptions of the model, related to the weak separability, are not usually tested in applications. This has been considered to be problematic in the interpretation of the results (e.g., Davis and Kruse 1993). However, testing is not always possible because of a lack of data. In many studies, when testing is made, the underlying assumptions of the model have not always been satisfied ( e.g., Alston et al. 1990). This is why some of the applications have refined the original assumptions of the Armington model, for example, by relaxing the homogeneity condition (Ito et al. 1990). Also, more general functional forms 24 and models which account for both non-homogeneity and the existence of variable elasticities of substitution have been presented (e.g. Henning and Martin 1989). A more flexible functional form, the translog form, presented by Christensen et ai. (1973), is applied in the present study (Hänninen 1994). This generalizes the original model from two to many factors and relaxes the restrictive assumption of constant elasticity of substitution applied by the Armington model and most of its applications. Thus, it was possible to obtain substitution elasticities for all possible country-pairs separately. Translog cost functions have been common in evaluating factor substitution and economies of scale in forest (and other) industries (e.g., Fuss 1977, Martinello 1985, Puttock and Prescott 1992, Hetemäki 1990). The present study formulates an export demand model system to estimate substitution elasticities between Finnish, Swedish, Canadian and Russian sawnwoods in the UK market (Hänninen 1994). Because sawnwood is an intermediate product, the model is derived from a cost function of the construction industry and not from the consumer's utility, as in Armington model. The two-stage demand model for sawnwood implies that a representative end-user in the UK first decides how much sawnwood and other (aggregate) inputs are required to produce a certain output. After this, he chooses between sawnwood from different countries of origin, including domestically produced sawnwood. Assuming cost-minimizing behavior for the sawnwood end user in British construction industry, the optimal sawnwood demands from different origins can be derived from the end user's cost function using Shephard's Lemma. The cost function is homogenous of degree one in prices and it is assumed to be translogarithmic (Christensen et ai. 1973). Thus, the demand functions in terms of shares can be presented as (3.1) (ainC/ain Pi) =PiXi/C= Si = Pi +ZsijlnPj, 25 where 5, = P,X,/C = the cost share of the /'th (z'=1,...,5) supplier country and i denotes Finland, Sweden, Canada, Russia and the rest of the world. Pj is the respective price of the jth (j= 1,...,5) supplier. The estimation of the system using the iterative Zellner estimation method (e.g., Pindyck and Rubinfeld 1988) (with the adding up criterion i.e.,lSj =l, and the homogeneity and symmetry conditions imposed) provides parameters from which the own price and substitution elasticities can be calculated for each observation. The translogarithmic model is more suitable in examining substitution between many countries than the earlier models which assumed constant elasticity of substitution. However, the problems of nonstationary (i.e., trended) data makes the interpretation of the results difficult. As a drawback in using a translogarithmic model, cross-equation restrictions are problematic in the estimation if time series properties are taken into account. For example, in the Johansen method (Johansen 1988) coefficient restrictions between cointegration vectors are not possible. 3.3 Testing the law of one price in forest products markets The Armington (Armington 1969) model assumes imperfect substitution between products from different countries of origin. This implies that, in the presence of price differences, substitution between supplier countries' products is measurable. The existence of price differences is explicitly studied by testing the law of one price (LOP) in the UK and German markets (Hänninen 1998 a and Hänninen et ai 1997). The law of one price is a variant of Purchasing Power Parity (PPP). PPP is a long-run relationship and states that, once converted to a common currency, national price levels should be equal. A large amount of empirical evidence on PPP shows that the real exchange rates (nominal exchange rates adjusted for differences in national price levels) tend toward PPP only in the very long run, the speed of adjustment being extremely slow, and that short-run deviations from PPP are large and volatile (Rogoff 1996). The origins of empirical PPP parity studies trace to the debate on how to restore the world financial system after its collapse during World War I, when gold standard was abandoned 26 (Rogoff 1996). Prior to the war, the exchange rate between two currencies tied to a gold standard simply reflected their relative gold values. After the war, countries faced the problem of deciding how to reset exchange rates with minimal disruption to prices and governement finances. Cassel (1921) was the first to study the subject empirically proposing to use of inflation differentials between countries to calculate the exchange rate changes needed to maintain PPP. Various versions of PPP are used in a vast number of applications, e.g., to choose the right initial exchange rate for a newly independent country, to forecast real exchange rates or to try to adjust price differences in international comparisons of income (Rogoff 1996). The law of one price is a building block of PPP, and it states that for any good i : where p, is the domestic-currency price of good i, pc is the foreign currency price and er is the exchange rate defined as the home-currency price of foreign currency. Thus, LOP implies that once prices are converted to a common currency, the same good should sell for the same price in different countries. The failure of the LOP is found in large number of studies. Of the early studies most notable were Isard (1977), who found deviations form the LOP between U.S., German, Canadian and Japanese exports of goods, such as industrial chemicals, paper and glass. Richardson (1978) found only some evidence of commodity price arbitrage in the exports of industrial products between U.S. and Canada. According to Giovannini (1988) price differentials existed in manufacturing goods. He also found, as Isard (1977) and Richardson (1978), that LOP deviations are highly correlated with exchange rate movements. Also, studies investigating export unit values from a single country to multiple destinations have found deviations from the LOP (e.g., Knetter 1989, 1993). Several reasons for LOP devations in traded goods can also be found in the literature. For example, tariffs, nontariff barriers and transportation costs may cause differences between prices in different countries. For some classes of goods, differing national standards may (3.2) pi=erpc, 27 weaken arbitrage. These different adjustment costs form a buffer within which nominal exchange rates can move without producing an immediate proportional response in relative domestic prices. Deviations from LOP in traded goods may also be explained by "pricing to market" theory (Krugman, 1987 and Dornbush, 1987). In this framework, oligopolistic suppliers can charge different prices for the same good in different countries. Conventionally, the LOP has been tested by regressing a commodity price in one country on the same commodity price in another country in common currency. Then, the slope coefficient is restricted to equal one and the intercept to equal zero. If the restrictions are not rejected, the law is concluded to hold. The flaw in these tests was the failure to take account of the time series properties of the variables. This was especially criticized in the 1980's and, of the early studies taking the nonstationarity of the variables into account, can be mentioned, e.g., Ardeni (1989), who used a bivariate Engle and Granger cointegration method (1987) to test the LOP. Single equation methods, however, inefficiently model the interaction between testable price variables and fail to take account of possible dynamics between them (e.g., Edison et al. 1997). More recently, systems methods have been developed, e.g., by Johansen (1988). With regard to LOP tests with more than two price variables, single equation methods are unable to find more than one cointegration vector, while according to Goodwin and Grennes (1994), full integration of the markets requires n-1 cointegration vectors among n variables. Although there is a wide literature on testing the law of one price for different commodities, there are few results for forest products. For example, Buongiorno and Uusivuori (1992), tested price differences in US pulp and paper exports to western European countries and Japan and found evidence for the LOP. They used the cointegration approach and a Dickey- Fuller type bivariate method. Johansen's cointegration method was used by Alavapati et al. (1997), who examined the price formation of Canadian pulp exports. They found support for the LOP between Canadian and American pulp prices. Jung and Doroodian (1994) used the same method in testing the law of one price between four regional softwood lumber markets in the United States. They interpreted the result as supportive of the LOP, but the 28 result is problematic, because it does not reveal for which of the four prices the law holds. In the present study, the Jung and Doroodian analysis was extended by conducting additional tests. These tests help to determine to which specific prices the law could possibly apply. 3.4 Exchange rate pass-through on forest product export prices Pass-through (PT) effects of exchange rates on prices have been analyzed for trade in many commodities and for aggregate imports and exports (see, e.g., the survey by Menon 1995) and the effects are found to vary widely by industry (e.g., Feenstra et al. 1996). The variation is related to industry characteristics, such as the degree of competition, product substitutability and the relative (domestic and foreign) market shares (see, e.g., Officer 1986, Menon 1995, Yang 1997). The large literature on PT arises from the discussion of fixed versus flexible exchange rates in international economics. After the breakdown of the Bretton Woods system of 1971-73, explanations were demanded for the question wether floating exchange rates would play an equilibrating role in trade balances. In this context, the underlying relationship between exchange rates and the prices of internationally traded goods have been widely examined. Following Dornbusch (1987), two extreme models to measure price relationships in the open economy literature can be presented. One assumes that the law of one price holds in the market (equation 3.1), in which case LOP belongs to PPP literature. The alternative model assumes that products from different origins are imperfect substitutes. Then, the relation between domestic and foreign price levels (real exchange rate) can be presented: where p ,■ is domestic price level, er is nominal exchange rate and pc is the foreign price level. Under imperfect competition, price will not equal marginal cost as firms have the possibility to charge a markup on production costs. If the markup is constant, exchange rate (3.3) § = pi/erpc, 29 movements change relative prices one-for-one, but, if the markup is variable, the issue becomes how the markup might vary in response to an exchange rate change. The reaction of markups is affected by, for example, the degree of substitutability between domestic and foreign goods and the degree of market integration or separation. The lower the degree of substitutability between goods, and the lower the degree of market integration (the presence of segmented markets), the greater will be the market power of suppliers (Menon 1995). The degree of the exchange rate effect on prices can be measured by the exchange rate pass-through (PT) coefficient, i.e., the percentage change in export prices (denoted in foreign currency) associated with a one percent change in the exchange rate. The magnitude of the PT may be O >...> X' P ) between the two sets of residual vectors RO, and Ri,. Residual Rol is obtained from regressing (Ax, )on the lagged differences and the deterministic variables (Ax,.i,...,Axt .k+i D,) and residual R t, is obtained from regressing (x,.k ) on (Ax,.i,...,Axt.k+i D, ). The resulting eigenvectors V" = [v'/ (...,v'p] are usually normalized as V"S uV= Ip. The estimators of cointegration vectors (3 are P = [v';,...,v'r], the eigenvectors corresponding to the r largest eigenvalues. The ML estimator of the cointegration space P reflects the r largest canonical correlations between the stationary and nonstationary parts of the system. It is important to note that the estimation method produces only the cointegration space. Thus, it is possible to give economic interpretation to the cointegration vectors only after identification. In testing the rank by the trace test, the null hypothesis is tested in each stage, against the general alternative that there are at most r cointegration vectors. The maximum eigenvalue test is given by the maximal likelhood statistics. The null hypothesis, that there are r cointegration vectors, is tested against the alternative that the rank is r : H0 : rank(n) =r + 1. The test statistic is Lmax(r) = -7" ln( 1 -A.' r+i). The asymptotic distributions of these likelihood ratio tests can be presented as multivariate versions of the Dickey-Fuller distribution and the distributions are also provided by Johansen and Juselius (1990). The present study applies the critical values at five percent (5.3) Ho: rank(n) Q), (4) Pm M = (P ml M, + PM2M2 +,..,+PmnMn) = E P„M> (5) PM~ PM(PMI>">PMN) un't C. where: C = total production cost Pm = an aggregator function, i.e. price index of sawnwood from different countries of origin (j = l,..,N) Po = prices of the other inputs Q = gross output. 208 Assuming that the cost function (6) is twice differentiate and using Shephard's duality theorem, the derivative of cost with respect to price equals the optimum quantity of a sawnwood from a certain supplier country. Cost minimizing behaviour implies (Fuss 1977, p. 9 and e.g. Greene 1990, pp. 527-528) that the demand functions for the suppliers, in terms of shares in the cost of the sawnwood aggregate, take the form: Where Sj = PjXj/C = the cost share of the ith factor and i= sawnwood imports from Finland, Sweden, Canada, Russia and the rest of the world. The respective cost share equations can be presented as: The above demand system is assumed to satisfy the adding-up criterion 2Sj=l and to impose the properties of the neoclassical production theory: The estimation the equation system produces parameters for the calculation of own-price and substitution elasticities for sawnwood imports from different supplier countries. The robustness of these estimates depends on the robustness of the estimation results. Thus, (6) C =Pw =B 0 + BF lnPF + Bs lnPs + BclnP c + BsulnPsu + BR lnP R + 1/2 [BpF(lnP F) 2 + BssClnPs) 2 + B cc(lnPc) 2 + B susu(lnPsu) 2 + 2 ] n p)(^nPs) + B FC (lnPF)(l nPc)"'"^FSu(l nPF)(l nPsu) + BFR(InP F)(lnPR)+ Bsc(lnPs)(lnPc)+ Bssu(lnPs)(lnPsu)+ BSR(InPs)(lnPR ) + öcsu(lnP c )(lnP su) + + öSUR(InPsu)(lnPR ), (7) (ainC/ainPi)(P/C) = PjXi/C = Si = B; +26^^, (8) SF =BF + BpplnPp + BpjlnPg + BFCInPc + + Bra lnPR S s = B s + BSF InPF + BsslnPs + B sclnPc + + BSRInPR S c = Bc + BCFInPF + + Bcc lnPc + + BCRInPR S su = Csu+ Csuf^PF+ ftsus'nPs BSUR^PR S R ~Br 4- BRF InPF + BRSInPs 4* BRC InPc + B lnPSLi + BKRInPK (9) Bf + Bs +Bc + Ben H* Br 1 + Bps + BpC + Breu + Bp» = 0 B SF + Bcj + Bsc + Bccti + Bsr = 0 B cf + Bcs + Bcc + Bcsu + BCR = 0 ®SUC = 0 BRP + BRS + Brc + Brsu + BRR = 0 and to satisfy the Slutsky symmetry condition B;j = , i+j. >i = cost shares of the supplier countries, i=F,S,C,SU,R, 'i = sawnwood prices of the supplier countries,i=F,S,C,SU,R, (F = Finland, S = Sweden, C = Canada, SU = Russia, R - the rest of the world) mere: ' M = unit cost of aggregate sawnwood imports ',= sawnwood prices from the supplier countries,i=F,S,C,SU,R, (F = Finland, S = Sweden, C = Canada, SU = Russia, R = the rest of the world) 209 the theoretical restrictions imposed by the underlying theory must be tested. In other words, the necessary and sufficient condition for strict quasi-concavity of the cost function in input prices is that the matrix of the computed elasticities (Hessian matrix) must be negative semidefinite at each observation point. (Berndt 1991, p. 476 and 493). Moreover, the underlying cost function must be monotonically increasing in input prices. This means that the fitted cost shares must all be positive. The cost share equation systems must also satisfy the symmetry restrictions, which are tested by using the Wald test (e.g. Berndt 1991, p. 465). 3. THE OWN-PRICE AND SUBSTITUTION ELASTICITIES OF DEMAND For the translog cost function, the price elasticities can be presented in the following way. The own price elasticity of input demand can be written: and the cross-price elasticity of input demand can be presented in the form: (see e.g. Puttock & Prescott 1992, p. 1141). In these formulae: The formulae 12 and 13 are the Allen partial elasticities. The Morishima elasticity of substitution (MES) is used to measure the substitution effects. It can be defined according to e.g. Chambers (1988, p. 96) as: This elasticity of substitution is asymmetric and the classification of inputs i and j as Morishima substitutes or complements depends critically on which one of the input prices changes. According to 14, inputs i and j are Morishima substitutes (i.e. i is substituted for j) if and only if an increase in pj causes the input ratio x/x, to increase when p, is fixed. If the estimate of the Morishima elasticity of substitution is positive, the two inputs in question can be interpreted as Morishima substitutes or inputs substitutable for each other. If, on the contrary, the elasticity is negative, the inputs are Morishima complements. Because the elasticity estimates for the translog function normally differ (10) 6H =„& (11) Cjj =ffjjSj. (12) a, = (Bjj + SiS,)/S,Sj and (13) a, = (Bjj + S,(S, -1))/S 2 i( (14) MESjj = e, -ea where: Bij.6, = estimated coefficients of the cost share equations S, S, = the fitted cost shares for the supplier countries i and j 210 at every observation, they are usually computed at the mean data values (e.g. Greene 1990, p. 528). 4. DATA The estimation of the model requires time series data on quantities, prices and cost shares of sawnwood imports to the United Kingdom by supplier countries. The quantity of aggregate sawnwood input (M) demanded in the end use sector is described by the total imports of coniferous sawnwood to the United Kingdom. Changes in the quality or species composition that may have occurred during the years 1961-1990 could not be taken into account because of a lack of information. Sawnwood demanded from different countries of origin are described by the imports of coniferous sawnwood from Finland (F), Sweden (S), Canada (C), Russia (SU) and the rest of the countries (R). The quantities (cbm) and unit prices (f/cbm) of imported sawnwood are obtained from the Overseas Trade Statistics of the United Kingdom. The unit prices are based on the CIF (cost, incurance and freight) values. The series were also checked and compared with other sources (FAO: Yearbook of Forest Products, Finntimber: Statistical Yearbook, TTF: U.K. Yearbook, and Finland's official statistics of foreign trade) and corrected where necessary. The import quantities from the rest of the countries (R) are calculated as the residual MR = M-(MF +MS+MC+MSU). The respective import price PR is calculated as a weighted (weighted by cost shares) average of the countries included in the residual group. 5. ESTIMATION METHOD AND TIME SERIES PROPERTIES The study estimates the model by using only the cost share equations (8). In order to specify a stochastic framework for estimation, a random disturbance term is added to each cost share equation. The restriction of linear homogeneity is satisfied by dividing the price variables of the cost share equations by the prices of the residual countries (P„). Before the estimation, the time series properties of the cost share variables (Sj) and transformed price variables (P/P R ) were analysed. From the viewpoint of the statistical validity of the estimation results, it is important to ensure that the time series are stationary i.e. 1(0) processes. A time series is said to be (weakly) stationary if its first two moments, i.e. mean and variance, are constant. Many economic time series do not satisfy the stationarity properties, they are often 1(1) processes. The properties of a stationary series 1(0) and a nonstationary series 1(1) are quite different. Thus, the degree of integration of the dependent and independent variables must match in the equations. If both are 1(0) processes, unbiased parameter estimates 211 can be obtained and the interpretation of the t-values is standard. However, if both are 1(1) processes and the error term is 1(0), unbiased estimates can be obtained, but the t values of the parameter estimates do not have standard interpretations. In this case, the dependent (y,) and independent variables (z,) are said to be integrated. If y, is 1(0) and some of the dependent variables are 1(1), results are not reliable, unless the subset of variables z, cointegrates to 1(0). In order to make conclusions concerning the robustness of the estimation results, the properties of the time series were examined by using autocorrelation functions, autoregressive processes of the series and normality and stationarity tests. Summing up the test results, the stationarity of the variables required by the estimation method is not fulfilled in the model, the variables seem to be 1(1) series (Hänninen, 1993). The demand system (8) is first estimated equation by equation using the ordinary least squares method (OLS). Then the symmetry restrictions are imposed, and the systems are estimated by using Zellner's seemingly unrelated estimator (ZEF) (Pindyck & Rubinfeld, 1988, pp. 331-334). Because the cost shares sum up to unity at each observation over all equations, only four of the five share equations are linearly independent. The common procedure to handle singular systems is to drop an arbitrary equation and then estimate the remaining share equations by using a method that is invariant to the excluded equation, (e.g. Berndt, 1991, pp. 472-473). However, no information is lost, because the parameters of the excluded equation can be calculated by using the remaining equations and the parameter restrictions (9) (see e.g. Berndt, 1991, pp. 472-473). 6. ESTIMATION RESULTS The Zellner iterative system estimation method with symmetry restrictions produced the following results for the cost share equations: (15) Cost share of Finland: S F = 0.21 - 0.171nPF + o.lolnPs + 0.021nPc - 0.021nPsu (34.18)* (-3.10)* (1.42) (0.41) (-0.58) DW=l.67, R 2 =.30 Cost share of Sweden: S s = 0.24 +o.lolnPF + 0.021nPs + 0.151nPc - 0.211nPsu (20.46)* (1.42) (0.15) (2.20)* (-2.86)* DW=O.36, R 2 =.05 Cost share of Canada: S c =O.lB + 0.021nPF + 0.151nPs - 0.151nPc + 0.031nPsu (20.71)* (0.41) (2.20)* (-2.78)* (0.81) DW=O.B5, R J =.3O 212 Cost share of Russia: The t values are presented in parentheses under the coefficients and the statistically significant coefficients (at the 5 per cent level of significance) are marked with *. However, the interpretation of the statistical significance of the coefficients is problematic because the variables are 1(1) series. The estimated coefficients are unbiased, if all the variables really are 1(1) series and if the error terms are 1(0) processes. Here, the residuals may be 1(0) processes, because they seem to have tendency to return to the mean and the mean seems to be near zero (Hänninen, 1993). However, in order to draw proper conclusions about the stationarity of the residuals they should be tested. Because the system estimation does not maximize the individual equation R 2 , it is not an appropriate measure of goodness-of-fit in an equation system context. Instead, some other measure is needed to evaluate the results (see e.g. Berndt, 1991, p. 486). The coefficients for the omitted residual countries, S R , are calculated by utilizing the estimation results of the above presented equations and the restrictions (9). By using the above symbols, the result is as follows: The fitted values of all the estimated cost shares are positive, which indicates that the monotonicity condition is satisfied. The computed Wald test value (7.16) indicates, that the symmetry restrictions are not rejected in the model. 6. ESTIMATES FOR SUBSTITUTION AND OWN-PRICE ELASTICITIES The long-run own-price and substitution elasticities of sawnwood demand from the supplier countries were computed by using the estimation results 15-16 and the formulae 10-14. The own-price elasticities are presented in Table 1. S su = 0.21 - 0.021 nP F - 0.211 nPs + 0.031 nPc + 0.161 nPsu (28.70)* (-0.58) (-2.86)* (0.81) (2.44)* DW=O.59, R 2 =.34 (16) Cost share of the residual countries: S R = 0.16 +o.oBlnPF -0.051nPs -0.051nPc +0.031nPsu -0.01PR. where: lnP F = ln(Pp/P R) = relative price from Finland lnP s : = n il n Sweden lnP c = ln(Pc/PR) = n II ii Canada lnP Su= = tl n n Russia 213 Table 1: Long run own-price elasticities for sawnwood from different supplier countries, 1961-1990, 1961-1975 and 1976-1990. *) The underlying parameter estimate (from equations 15) is statistically significant at 5 % level of significance. The resulting own-price elasticities of sawnwood demand from Finland, Sweden, Canada and the residual countries are of the (right) negative sign (Table 1). For Russia the elasticity is negative only in some years of the period (Hänninen, 1993) and its mean values are positive. Before discussing more about the estimated elasticities, it must be reminded that the interpretation of the statistical significance of the elasticities is problematic, because the variables of the cost share equations were not stationary. Nevertheless, it is assumed here, that the computed own-price and substitution elasticities are statistically significant, if the underlying parameter estimates p i; and p ;j (in the estimated cost share equations 15) are statistically significant at the 5 per cent level of significance. According to the estimation results, demand from Finland and Canada appear to be elastic. This means, for example, that a 1 percent rise in the price of Finnish sawnwood would decrease the demand for it by 1.60 percent. Because of price- elastic demand, Finland and Canada could affect their export earnings by pricing policy in the United Kingdom. They could increase their export quantities and total export revenues by lowering the price. Price rises are, however, problematic. If prices are increased, the market shares are lost to the competitors. When increasing costs cause pressure to the prices, one possibility to minimize the impact is to ensure that price changes are in line with those of the competitors. Because Finland's and the other suppliers' price movements seem to have been rather uniform on average, it seems, that Finland has not, however, been able to much benefit from pricing policy. Therefore, the development of production costs as compared to the competitors' costs and exchange rates have an important role in Finland's sawnwood exports. For the Soviet Union the own-price elasticity estimate is almost 0 and of the wrong sign and it is not statistically significant. Possible explanations for the zero price-elasticity of Russian sawnwood are different motives for sawnwood exports and different way of trading. Sawnwood demand from Sweden and from the residual countries seem to be price-inelastic in the United Kingdom market. The low price elasticity of Sweden's sawnwood indicates that it could have more possibilities for free pricing than its Supplier Time periods country 1961-1990 1961-1975 1976-1990 «a eii Finland -1.62* -1.54 -1.71 Sweden -0.69 -0.68 -0.69 Canada -1.58* -1.69 -1.46 Russia 0.06 0.00 0.13 Others -0.91 -0.89 -0.89 214 competitor, Finland. In price-inelastic market it is possible to raise the product price if production costs increase, without losing market share significantly, ceteris paribus. Because Finland seem not to be able to use effective pricing policy to increase its export quantities and revenues in the United Kingdom market, it could try to push the price elasticity of sawnwood more near to zero. Price-inelastic demand could give more possibilities in free pricing when the production costs are increasing. The price elasticity of the product can be decreased by marketing activities, for example, by different promotional strategies and branding that make the product more unique in the eyes of the customers. The Morishima elasticities of substitution (MES), obtained here, are not necessarily statistically significant (Table 2). However, some inferences, based on their computed values, are made below. According to the estimates, substitutability is the dominating feature. Previous studies also indicate substitutability between Finland and the other suppliers' sawnwood in the United Kingdom market (e.g. Hänninen 1986; Tervo et ai. 1988). For Russia the MES estimate could not be computed, because its own-price elasticity was of the wrong sign (Table 1). The substitution elasticities calculated for different periods (Table 2) indicate that their values have not changed much during the period studied. Table 2: Long run Morishima elasticities of substitution (MES) for sawnwood from different supplier countries, 1961-1990, 1961-1975 and 1976-1990. MES between Time periods supplier countries 1961-1990 1961-1975 1976-1990 MES , MES, M E Si] Finland / Sweden (FS) 1.40 1.36 1.44 / Canada (FC) 1.85 1.94 1.75 / others (FR) 1.47 1.44 1.50 Sweden / Finland (SF) 2.22 2.15 2.29 / Canada (CS) 2.38 2.47 2.29 / others (SR) 0.85 0.86 0.85 Canada/ Finland (CF) 1.91 1.85 1.97 / Sweden (CS) 1.70 1.79 1.60 / others (CR) 0.82 0.79 0.84 Others / Finland (RF) 2.30 2.26 2.34 " / Sweden (RS) 0.61 0.60 0.63 / Canada (RC) 1.48 1.56 1.41 215 It can be seen from Table 2 that the Morishima elasticities of substitution are not symmetric. For example, a 1 per cent rise in the price of Finnish sawnwood would increase the relative quantity demanded from Sweden (Mj/Mp) by about 2 per cent. On the other hand, a 1 per cent rise in the price of Swedish sawnwood would increase the relative quantity demanded from Finland (MF/MS) by only about 1.4 per cent. This means that a rise in Sweden's price causes a smaller increase in demand from Finland than the increase in demand from Sweden caused by a rise in Finland's price. From this, we can conlude, that it has been easier to substitute Swedish sawnwood for Finnish sawnwood than to substitute Finnish sawnwood for Swedish sawnwood. When comparing the substitution elasticities between Finland and its other competitors, Canada and the residual countries, the same kind of conclusion can be drawn. In general, when prices have increased, it has been easier to substitute sawnwood from competing countries for sawnwood from Finland, than vice versa: Sweden/Finland = MES-SF= 2.22 > MES-FS= 1.40 Canada/Finland = MES-CF= 1.91 > MES-FC= 1.85 Others/Finland = MES-RF= 2.30 > MES-FR= 1.47. One should, however, notice that the interpretation of the statistical significancy of MES estimates is problematic and that the differences between the elasticities are rather small. 7. CONCLUSION The two-level demand system and the translogarithmic function were quite satisfactory approaches in the calculation of the substitution elasticities between Finland and its competitor countries in the U.K. sawnwood import demand. The resulting estimates for the Morishima elasticities of substitution indicate that sawnwood from Finland, Sweden and Canada are substitutes in the markets of the United Kingdom. Compared to the previous research the present study produced the following additional information on the substitution. First, the estimated substitution elasticities vary pairwise between supplier countries, because constant elasticity of substitution was not assumed. Second, the magnitudes of the Morishima elasticities indicate that it is easier to substitute sawnwood from competing countries for Finnish sawnwood, than to substitute sawnwood from Finland for competitors' sawnwood when prices are increasing. Even though the approach of the study was quite satisfactory in the estimation of the elasticities, the interpretation of the statistical significancy of the parameters was problematic because of the non-stationarity of the variables. So, in order to get more robust estimates of the parameters, the estimation method should be developed further. The time series properties of the variables should be taken into account in the estimation and also possible dynamic features of sawnwood import demand of the United Kingdom could be included into the model. 216 LITERATURE CITED Armington, P.S. 1969: A Theory of demand for products distinguished by place of production. IMF Staff Papers, 16(1): pp. 159-176. Berndt, E. 1991: The practice of econometricsxlassic and contemporary. Addison-Wesley Publishing Company, Inc., The United States, 702 pp. Blackorby, C. & R.R. Russel 1989: Will the real elasticity of substitution please stand up? - (A comparison of the Allen/Uzawa and Morishima elasticities). American Economic Review 79(4): pp. 882-888. Chambers, R.G. 1988: Applied production analysis - A dual approach. Cambridge University Press, New York, 331 pp. Chou, J.-J. & J.Buongiorno 1982: United States demand for hardwood plywood imports - a distributed lag model. Agricultural Systems 8(3): pp. 225-239. Chou, J.-J. & J.Buongiorno 1983: United States demand for hardwood plywood imports by country of origin. Forest Science 29(2): pp. 225-237. Chou, J.J. & J. Buongiorno 1984: Demand functions for U. S. forest products exports to the European Eonomic Community. Wood and Fiber Science 16(2): pp. 158-168. Christensen, L.R., D.W.Jorgenson & J.J.Lau 1973: Transcendental logarithmic production frontiers. Review of Economics and Statistics, 55: pp.2B-45. Diewert, W.E. 1971: An application of the Shephard duality theorem - A generalized Leontief production function. Journal of Political Economy, 79: pp. 481-507. Fuss, M.A. 1977: The demand for energy in Canadian manufacturing. An example of the estimation of production structures with many inputs. Journal of Econometrics, 5: pp.B9-16. Greene, W.H. 1990: Econometric analysis. MacMillan Publishing Company. New York. 783 pp. Hseu, J-S & J.Buongiorno 1993: Price elasticities of substitution between species in the demand of U.S. softwood lumber imports from Canada. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 23: pp. 591-597. Hänninen, R. 1986: Suomen sahatavaran vientikysyntä Länsi-Euroopassa vuosina 1962- 1983. (English summary: Demand for Finnish sawnwood exports in western Europe, 1962-1983). Folia Forestalia, 657, 25 pp. Hänninen, R. 1993: The effect of relative price variations on the sawnwood imports to the United Kingdom from Finland. Licentiate thesis in forest products marketing, University of Helsinki, 108 pp. Pindyck, R.S. & D.L.Rubinfeld 1988: Econometric models and economic forecasts. Second edition, McGraw-Hill Inc. 630 pp. Puttock, G.D. & D.M.Prescott 1992: Factor substitution and economies of scale in the southern Ontario hardwood sawmilling industry. Canadian Journal of Forest Research, 22: pp. 1139-1146. Solow, R.M. 1955-56: The production function and the theory of capital. The Review of Economic Studies, 23: pp.lol-108. Tervo, M., J.Mäkelä & R.Hänninen 1988: Dynaaminen kysyntämalli Ison-Britannian maittaiselle sahatavaran tuonnille (English summary: A dynamic demand model for British imports of sawnwood from different countries). Finnish Forest Research Institute, Research Papers, 313, 35 pp. Varian, H.L. 1984: Microeconomic analysis. Second edition, W.W. Norton & Company. New York, 348 pp. 217 Statistical Sources: CSO, Overseas Trade Statistics of the United Kingdom, 1960-1990. FAO, Yearbook of Forest Products, 1960-1990. Rome. Finntimber, Statistical Yearbook. Finnish Timber Exporters' Association. Helsinki. SVT, Foreing Trade, Finland, Al, from different years. Helsinki. TTF, U.K. Yearbook of Timber Statistics, 1976 and 1983-85. Charles K. Norman (ed.). Published by the Timber Trade Federation, London. II 17 The Law of One Price in United Kingdom Soft Sawnwood Imports—A Cointegration Approach Riitta H. Hänninen ABSTRACT. The law of one price states that prices of homogenous commodities, defined in a common currency, are equal throughout the world. It implies cointegration of prices. In the present study, the law was tested for imports of soft sawnwood to the United Kingdom from Finland, Sweden, Canada, and Russia using the concept of cointegration. The data are quarterly and cover the period 1978-1992. The study used the multivariate cointegration method of Johansen instead of the bivariate method commonly used in earlier studies. The existence of the law was tested simultaneously for all four import prices and separately for pairs of prices. The results do not support the "law" but instead indicate the existence of differences over the long run between different suppliers' sawnwood prices. This suggests that imperfect competition models should be used in explaining and forecasting UK sawnwood imports. The results also raise an important issue concerning testing for competition in forest products markets, which is not usually done in connection with the modeling of markets. For. Sci. 44(l):17-23. Additional Key Words: Forest products, international trade, Johansen's method, unit root econometrics. In this study the law of one price is tested for United Kingdom (UK) sawnwood imports from its main sup plier countries, Sweden, Finland, Canada, and Russia. The law of one price is a conventional assumption in studies of commodity trade. It states that each good has a single price, defined in a common currency unit, throughout the world (Isard 1977). A number of studies that modeled forest product markets and trade have assumed the law was correct, but several other studies have allowed for price differences in the market. The validity of the assumption has not usually been tested. However, reliable information about the exist ence of price differences in the market is important when choosing a suitable modeling strategy. Allowance is made for price differences between coun tries of destination or countries of origin, for example, in trade models based on the theory of Armington (1969). The same is true of studies modeling trade in plywood (e.g., Chou and Buongiorno 1983), pulp and paper (e.g., Blatner 1989), and sawnwood (e.g., Castillo and Laarman 1984, Mohd Shahwahid 1991, Hseu and Buongiorno 1993, Hänninen 1994). The existence of price differences has been justified, for example, by Buongiorno et al. (1979, p. 643), who state that lumber quality (even for the same species and grade), business practices, habits, and attachment to a particular supplier country or specific supplier may differ depending on the country of origin. The other approach, which assumes the law of one price, is used, for example, in the Timber Assessment Market Model (Adams and Haynes 1980) and in the Global Trade Model (Dykstra and Kallio 1987). Brännlund et ai. (1982) used it in modeling Sweden's trade in different forest prod ucts, as did Buongiorno and Gilles (1984) in modeling newsprint trade and Boyd and Krutilla (1987) in modeling lumber trade. There are several studies testing the law of one price for different commodities, and the results do not often support the law (c.f., Isard 1977, Ardeni 1989, Knetter 1993). How ever, there are only a few studies testing the law for forest products. For example, Buongiorno and Uusivuori (1992), tested price differences in US pulp and paper exports to western European countries and Japan. They used the cointegration approach and the Dickey-Fuller type bivariate method, as did, e.g., Ardeni (1989), and found evidence for the law of one price. Because simultaneity cannot be taken into account in a bivariate testing method, the earlier results may have suffered from simultaneity problems. Nor does the Riitta H. Hänninen, Researcher of Forest Economics, Forest Research Institute, Helsinki Research Centre, Unioninkatu 40 A, 00170 Helsinki, Finland. Phone: +358 9 85705746; Fax: +358 9 85705717; E-mail: riitta.hanninen@metla.fi. Acknowledgments: The author wishes to thank Jari Kuuluvainen, Lauri Hetemäki, Jussi Uusivuori, and Antti Ripatti for their valuable comments to improve the manuscript and Metsämiesten Säätiö Foundation for financial support. Manuscript received August 31,1995. Accepted November 1,1996, Copyright © 1998 by the Society of American Foresters Reprinted from Forest Science, Vol. 44, No. 1, February 1998. Not for further reproduction. 18 Forest Science 44(1) 1998 multivariate cointegration method of Engle and Granger (1987) account for simultaneity. By contrast, in the test procedure presented by Johansen (1988) and Johansen and Juselius (1990, 1992), the price equations can be estimated simultaneously. Jung and Doroodian (1994) used Johansen's procedure in testing the law for four regional softwood lumber markets in the United States and found support for the law. However, they did not resolve the question: for which two of the four prices does the law hold. They found one cointegration relationship, which means that the law of one price cannot be valid for all four prices simultaneously. In the present study, Johansen's procedure was also used, but the Jung and Doroodian analysis was extended by conducting addi tional tests. These tests help to determine for which spe cific prices the law could possibly hold. Also, the unit root tests for price series are carried out within the same framework. The present study tested the law of one price in the UK sawnwood markets for the period 1978 to 1992. The law implies that prices of sawnwood from different countries should be equal in the UK market. If this is true, the market can be characterized as a perfectly competitive market, in which sawnwoods from the supplier countries were per fect substitutes for each other. Unlike earlier studies, a complete set of tests was carried out, and the multivariate method with simultaneous maximum likelihood estima tion was used to allow for more reliable statistical infer ence. Contrary to the traditional assumption and to the results of Buongiorno and Uusivuori (1992), the present results do not support the law. Testing the Law of One Price In the present study, the law of one price for UKsawn wood imports was tested using the concept of cointegration for nonstationary time series. The study used the multivariate testing method of Johansen (Johansen 1988, Johansen and Juselius 1990, 1992) instead of the bivariate tests usually applied in earlier studies. It also expanded the test for soft wood lumber prices (Jung and Doroodian 1994) by running additional tests in Johansen's framework: the stationarity of the price variables was examined and the law of one price was tested for pairs of prices. The testing procedure consisted of two stages. First, it was tested whether the law holds simultaneously for Finn ish, Swedish, Canadian, and Russian prices. For this pur pose, the cointegration rank of the price data was deter mined. The rank defines how many cointegration vectors, r, can be found in the data. Second, the law was tested for pairs of prices under r. As an example of the testing of the law, let Pit and Pj, be sawnwood prices of two supplier countries, expressed in the UK currency. Assuming no transportation costs, the law of one price implies that in equilibrium Pit = Pjt. Then, the law can be stated as Using lower case letters to denote logarithms and includ ing an error term, Equation (I) can be written as The law of one price implies that the constant term, a, should not be significantly different from zero, b should not be significantly different from one, and Uy, should be distrib uted identically and independently. Because price levels are nonstationary, the ordinary least squares method would not produce reliable inferences. Therefore, the cointegration method was used. Assuming the law holds. Equation (2) can also be written as the difference between the two prices, Ujj, = pit ~Pjr If ,is 1(0), the prices are cointegrated and the law holds. Due to this proportionality of prices, their coeffi cients, P,| and P;1 , in the estimated cointegration vector (Pi) should be equal but of opposite sign: P (! = — py, . This property is used in the following. In the case of four price variables, which in this study are prices of sawnwood from Finland, Sweden, Canada, and Russia, the law of one price can be written = p 2l =Py = pit in equilibrium. This can also be presented with three relationships that form the first null hypothesis: Hypothesis (3) was tested by examining whether there are three cointegration vectors in the cointegration space. If this is true, the law holds for all four prices simultaneously. The second stage of the testing procedure was the pairwise test of the law under r. Because only one cointegration vector was found, the law cannot hold for four prices simulta neously. Instead, it can hold for two of the prices. The second null hypothesis is then This hypothesis was tested by investigating whether the restriction P( j = — Py| is valid for any two prices in the cointegration vector Pj (restriction A 4 in Appendix 1). If the hypothesis (4) is rejected, the law of one price is also rejected for that price pair. Data The data for the study consisted of prices of soft sawnwood imported to the UK market from Finland, Sweden, Canada, and Russia. The data were quarterly, seasonally unadjusted, and covered the period from 1978 to 1992. The four supplier countries together have accounted for about 80% of UK sawnwood imports during the period studied, and their indi vidual import shares have been quite similar (Table 1). This means that suppliers have not differed much in terms of market power. The import prices of sawnwood from Finland, Sweden, Canada, and Russia to the UK were described by the average import unit values (£/m 3 ) based on CIF (including cost, Pu = (1) pu = a + bp j, + u,j, (2) »o- Pi, = P 2,' Pi, = Pi, and Pi, = Pi, (3) Ho- Pi, = Pj, (' = 1 4 . '* 7) (4) Forest Science 44(I) 1998 19 Table 1. Suppliers' percentage shares of sawnwood imports to the United Kingdom. insurance, and freight) figures. Data on quantities and values of sawnwood (SITC 248.2-3) imports were taken from the Overseas Trade Statistics of the United Kingdom (CSO) for the period 1978-1990 and from the intra-and extra-EU trade statistics (European Commission) for the period 1990-1992. The exchange rate, £/ECU, needed for the observations over the period 1990-1992 was obtained from International Mon etary Fund (IMF) statistics. The unit price series were de flated by the UK producer price index (1985 = 100) obtained from the Main Economic Indicators (OECD). All the analysis of the study was carried out using real price series in loga rithms. Graphs of the prices of sawnwood show sharp fluctuations during the period studied, 1978-1992 (Appendix 2). Fluctua tions in the suppliers' prices have widened since the 19605, which is presumably due to the two main events in the international financial markets: the breakdown of the Bretton Woods system in 1971-1973 and the oil crises in the middle of the 19705. After the breakdown of 1971-1973, the interna tional currency system changed; many countries let their currency float, while Finland and Sweden each used a cur rency index to define the average exchange rate. Average import unit values were used to describe prices because more disaggregated data on the quality composition of each supplier's sawnwood were not available for the period studied. This means that sawnwood imported from the four supplier countries to the UK is assumed to be homog enous enough to allow for reliable testing of the law of one price using unit values. For Finnish, Swedish, and Russian sawnwood, the assumption is well justified as producers in these countries have much the same raw material and end-use sectors. Canadian sawnwood competes with the other suppli ers' sawnwood mainly in the market for structural sawnwood. Moreover, tree species of Canadian sawnwood differ from the competitors' species (NUTEK 1992). This means that sawnwood from Canada may not be exactly comparable to the other suppliers' sawnwood, which must be taken into account in drawing conclusions. Method and Empirical Results Cointegration and Stationarity of Price Variables The cointegration method presupposes that the series to be tested are nonstationary unit root processes. The existence of a unit root was first tested using the Augmented Dickey- Fuller (ADF) test (Dickey and Fuller 1979). After the cointegration estimation, the variables were also tested by Johansen's method, and the results were compared. The ADF test results presented in Table 2 are based on the equation including constant, trend, seasonals, and three lags. Accord ing to the results, the levels of the price series seem to be nonstationary, while the first differences are stationary. Thus, it is concluded that all the levels of the prices are nonstationary /(l) processes. The inferences regarding nonstationarity are invariant to the different numbers of lags (1 to 5) included in the test equation. Hypothesis testing was initiated by determining the cointegration rank, r, which defines the number of cointegration vectors in the price data. For this purpose, Johansen's method was applied. Johansen's method uses a statistical model that is a p-dimensional VAR(k) process. It can be reparameterized in error correction form as where Ax, is a 1(0) vector, (X is a vector of constant terms, D, is a seasonal dummy, and k is the lag length (k = 1 ~..,A0 The constant term can be restricted to the cointegration space in the estimation if there is no linear trend in the data. r, rt_! and n = -/ + n, +,...,+ are coefficient matrices, n is the matrix of long-run coefficients, and it can be decomposed into a matrix of loadings, a, and a matrix of cointegrating vectors, (3, i.e., fl = ap\ The Table 2. The Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) and Johansen unit root test results for prices of sawnwood with three lags. At, = r,A*M + +rt .,Ax,.t+l + n*,.* + + 1, r > 1 against r >2, etc. The hypothesis (Al) is tested using the likelihood ratio test of the form where T is the number of observations and the Xfs are the smallest squared canonical correlations (eigenvalues). The testing strategy is a multivariate analogue of the Dickey- Fuller (1979) test. When the number of cointegration vectors, r, is deter mined by the data, it is possible to test different hypotheses by restricting the cointegration vectors, p, or their weights, a. Testing is done by estimating Model (5) with restric tions and comparing the results to the Model (5) without restrictions. The test statistics are asymptotically y} dis tributed. Under r, the Johansen method (Johansen and Juselius 1990, 1992) formulates the following restriction on p, which can be used to test the stationarity of a variable: In (A 3), p is the dimension of the model (here p = 4), r is the number of cointegration vectors, of which rj vectors H 0 : rank(fl) < r (Al) -2 In (Q) = -r£ln(l-X,.) (A 2) i=r+l P = («,¥) (A 3) where H(p x r,), *|/( p x r 2) and /■ =/j +r 2 Forest Science 44(1) 1998 23 are known a priori. Matrix H is a design matrix, where the restriction on the (3 matrix is formulated by the researcher. The test can be done by estimating Model (5) with restric tions, so that r , cointegration vectors are restricted, and the remaining r2 cointegration vectors (included in matrix y) are unrestricted. Because the number of cointegration relations was found to be one, r2 - 0 and r l =1 in the present study. Stationarity is tested by restricting the coefficient of the testable variable (P,l) to unity and the other coefficients to zero in the cointegration vector p, and by examining whether the result ing linear combination is stationary. These restrictions are defined by design matrices H, which are of the form (1,0,0,0), (0,1,0,0), etc. Each variable is tested separately by restricting the coefficients respectively in the //matrix. The null hypoth esis for the Johansen test is stationarity. The hypothesis presented in Equation (4), i.e., the law of one price by pairs of prices, can be tested using the following restriction of Johansen: In (A 4) the restrictions are defined by p3i=-i Pi 1=0» p21=l» Pjl=-I 9.88* Note: psk, pfk and pek are the newsprint prices of Sweden, Finland and Canada in the UK. "Critical x 2 value is 5.99 at the 5% level, the rejection of the law of one price. Testable Test (under r=l) a=0 price (LR test statistic") Sweden, psk 1.32 Finland, pfk 1.30 Canada, pek 9.71* "Critical x 2 value 3.84 at the 5% level. •denotes the rejection of weak cxogencity. 1952 Can. J. For. Res. Vol. 27, 1997 Blatner, K. A. 1989. An approach to the estimation of import price elasticities by supplier. For. Sci. 35(1): 30-41. Booth, D.L., Kanctkar, V., Vcrtinsky, 1., and Whistler, D. 1991. An empirical model of capacity expansion and pricing in an oligopoly with barometric price leadership: a case study of newsprint indus try in North America. J. Ind. Econ. 39(3): 255-276. Brännlund, R., and Löfgren, K.G. 1995. Cyclical dumping and corre lated business cycles in imperfect markets: empirical applications to the Canadian pulp and paper industry. Appl. Econ. 27: 1081-1091. Brännlund, R., Lundberg, L., and Wiberg, A. 1982. Determinants of Swedish market shares for pulp, paper and sawnwood in Europe. Department of Forest Economics, Swedish University of Agricul tural Sciences, Umeä. Rep. 36. Buongiorno, J., and Gilless, J.K. 1984. A model of international trade of forest products, with an application to newsprint. J. World For. Res. Manag. 1: 65-80. Buongiorno, J., and Uusivuori, J. 1992. The law of one price in the trade of forest products: co-intcgration tests for U.S. exports of pulp and paper. For. Sci. 38(3): 539-553. Chou, J-J., and Buongiorno, J. 1983. United States demand for hard wood plywood imports by country of origin. For. Sci. 29(2): 225-237. CSO. 1980-1994. Overseas trade statistics of the United Kingdom, CSO, London. Dagcnais, M. 1976. The determination of newsprint prices. Can. J. Econ. IX: 442-461. Dickey, D.A., and Fuller, W.A. 1979. Distribution of estimates for autoregrcssivc time scries with unit root. J. Am. Stat. Assoc. 74: 427-431. Doornik, J.A., and Hendry, D.F. 1994. PcFiml 8.0. Interactive econometric modelling of dynamic systems. Institute of Econom ics and Statistics, University of Oxford. International Thomson Publishing, London. Dykstra, D.P., and Kallio, M. 1987. Introduction to the II AS A Forest Sector Model. In The global forest sector: an analytical perspec tive. Edited by M. Kallio, D.P. Dykstra, and C.S. Binkley. John Wiley & Sons, Chichester, pp. 139-167. Englc, R.F., and Granger, C.W.J. 1987. Co-integration and error cor rection: representation, estimation and testing. Econometrica, 55(2): 251-276. Gonzalo, J. 1994. Five alternative methods of estimating long-run equilibrium relationships. J. Econom. 60: 203-233. Goodwin, 8.K., and Grennes, T.J. 1994. Real interest rate equaliza tion and the integration of international financial markets. J. Int. Money and Fin. 13: 107-124. Hänninen, R. 1994. Price elasticities of substitution between Finland and the other supplier countries in the demand for the United Kingdom sawnwood imports. In Proceedings of the Biennial meeting of the Scandinavian forest economics, 22-25 Nov. 1994, Gillcleje, Denmark. Edited by Finn Helles and Michael Linddal. Department of Economics and Natural Resources, Royal Veteri nary and Agricultural University, Copenhagen, Denmark. Scand. For. Econ. 35: 204-217. Hänninen, R. 1998. The law of one price in the United Kingdom soft sawnwood imports—a cointcgration approach. For. Sci. 44(1). In press. Hseu, J-S., and Buongiorno, J. 1993. Price elasticities of substitution between species in the demand of U.S. softwood lumber imports from Canada. Can. J. For. Res. 23: 591-597. Isard, P. 1977. How far can wc push the "law of one price"? Am. Econ. Rev. 67(5): 942-948. Johansen, S. 1988. Statistical analysis of cointcgration vectors. J. Econ. Dynam.Control, 12: 231-254. Johansen, S. 1992. Cointcgration in partial systems and the efficiency of single equation analysis. J. Econom. 52: 389-402. Johansen, S. 1995. Likelihood based inference in cointcgrated vector autoregrcssivc models. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Johansen, S., and Juselius, K. 1990. Maximum likelihood estimation and inference on cointcgration — with applications to the demand for money. Oxford Bull. Econ. Stat. 52: 169^-210. Johansen, S., and Juselius, K. 1992. Structural tests in a multivariate cointegration analysis of the PPP and the UIP for UK. J. Econom. 53:211-244. Jung, C., and Doroodian, K. 1994. The law of one price for U.S. softwood lumber: a multivariate cointcgration test. For. Sci. 40(5): 595-600. Knetter, M.M. 1993. International comparisons of pricing-to-inarkct behavior. Am. Econ. Rev. 83(3): 473-486. Laaksonen, S., Toppincn, A., Hänninen, R., and Kuuluvainen, J. 1997. Cointcgration in Finnish paper exports to the United King dom. J. For. Econ. 3(2): 171-185. OECD. 1962-1991, 1993. Main economic indicators, historical sta tistics. Organization for Economic Co-operation and Develop ment, Paris. Officer, L.H. 1986. The law of one price cannot be rejected: two tests based on the tradable/nontradablc price ratio. J. Macroccon. 8: 159-182. Silvapullc, P., and Jayasuriya, S. 1994. Testing for Philippines rice market integration: a multiple cointcgration approach. J. Agric. Econ. 45: 369-380. Stock, J.H. 1987. Asymptotic properties of least squares estimators of cointcgration vectors. Econometrica, 55: 1035-1056. O 1997 NRC Canada IV Silva Fennica 32(1) research articles 61 Exchange Rate Changes and the Finnish Sawn wood Demand and Price in the UK Market Riitta H. Hänninen Hänninen, R.H. 1998. Exchange rate changes and the Finnish sawnwood demand and price in the UK market. Silva Fennica 32(1): 61-73. This paper examines the long-run influence of exchange rate changes on the Finnish sawnwood price in the United Kingdom (UK) using quarterly data for the period 1978 1994. The degree of influence was measured by a pass-through coefficient (PT) obtained from a markup pricing relation of a system model. The model, which included export demand and price equations, was estimated with the cointegration method of Johansen. The results indicated a large PT, which means that exchange rate changes are reflected almost proportionately in Finnish export price expressed in pounds sterling. Thus, the Finnish price of sawnwood in pounds has lowered as a result of depreciation of the Finnish markka (FIM). This has improved Finnish competitiveness and market share in the UK. Appreciation of the FIM has had the opposite effect. It seems that Finnish exporters have made use of depreciations and devaluations of the FIM to maintain and increase their market shares but not necessarily their markups. For Finland, which is in the process of joining the European economic and monetary union (EMU), knowing the size of the PT is also important in assessing the economic impact of membership. Keywords exchange rate, export demand, Johansen's cointegration method, pass-through, sawnwood price, United Kingdom Author's address Forest Research Institute, Helsinki Research Centre, Unioninkatu 40 A, 00170 Helsinki, Finland Phone +358 9 8570 5746 E-mail riitta.hanninen@metla.fi Received 22 May 1997 Accepted 22 December 1997 1 Introduction This study examines the effects of exchange rate changes on Finland's sawnwood exports to the United Kingdom (UK), which is a major market for Finnish sawnwood. In 1996 the UK account- Ed for 18 percent of Finland's sawnwood ex ports (Facts and Figures 1997). Exchange rate effects are analysed by a demand and supply model for Finnish sawnwood exports. The focus of the study is on the exchange rate pass-through (PT), i.e. the percentage change in export prices Silva Fennica 32(1) research articles 62 associated with a one percent change in the ex change rate. If the exchange rate has a small effect on for eign currency prices, currency realignments should not have much effect on exports. Previous results are scanty for forest products, but they indicate that trade flows of forest products (meas ured in quantities) have not been very sensitive to exchange rate variations (Buongiorno et al. 1988). Also Uusivuori and Buongiorno (1990) found no long-run relationship between exchange rates and quantities of paper exports from Finland and Sweden to the USA. For Finland, which is in the process of joining the EMU, the magnitude of the exchange rate effect is important in assessing the economic impact of membership. In the EMU, it will no longer be possible to improve competitive ness by manipulating the exchange rate. Estimates of the degree of pass-through are also informative as to market competition, which is important in modeling trade flows. The pass-through concept can be defined as the extent to which a change in a country's nom inal exchange rate induces a price change in terms of the foreign currency. The magnitude of the pass-through also reflects the extent of mar ket competition. For example, in perfect compe tition, export prices in foreign currency do not change as a result of a devaluation (revaluation) of the exporter's currency. In this case, Finnish exporters' prices in FIM would increase (de crease), their markup margins would increase (decrease) and the PT would be zero. On the other hand, in imperfect competition Finnish ex porters could change their foreign currency pric es when the exchange rate changes. If exchange rate fluctuations were partly reflected in foreign currency prices and partly in FIM prices, PT would be between zero and unity. If PT is unity, Finnish exporters lower (raise) their foreign cur rency export prices pro rata to a devaluation (revaluation) of the FIM Pass-through has not been extensively studied for forest products trade, although it has been analyzed for trade in many other commodities and for aggregate imports and exports (see e.g. the survey Menon 1995). PT is found to vary widely by industry (e.g. Feenstra et al. 1996), which means that it is necessary to study pass through at the commodity level. Most of the few studies analyzing the PT for forest products deal with the USA. For example, there are very few results for Finnish exports. In the study of Vesa la (1992) PT for export prices of Finnish paper manufactures was found to be between 0.66 and 0.69 for western Europe and between 0.16 and 0.30 for the USA. According to Vesala, the small er PT for the USA is due to the large US domes tic market, in which the Finnish share is much smaller than in Europe. Other studies have also found that prices of several commodities import ed to the USA only slightly reflect changes in exchange rates (e.g. Yang 1997). Uusivuori and Buongiorno (1991) estimated PT for US forest products exports to Europe and Japan. Pass-through was incomplete in most of the product categories. However, in lumber ex ports to Japan, PT was high: from 0.79 to 1.04, depending on the species. Also in the study of Menon (1993 a), who estimated PTs for Austral ian imports, wood products had a relatively high PT (0.80), while for paper and board the PT was 0.45. The earlier results indicate that PT is high er for wood industry products than for paper products. However, exact conclusions about the size of the PT for forest products are difficult to draw, because studies are scarce and they con cern only a few products and countries. Based on the earlier models for Finnish sawn wood exports to the UK (e.g. Hänninen 1986, Tervo et al. 1988, Hänninen 1994) and studies that test arbitrage in UK sawnwood imports (Hän ninen 1998), it can be assumed that the PT is relatively large. The assumption is also support ed by the structure of UK sawnwood imports, which is dominated by four large supplier coun tries, i.e. Finland, Sweden, Canada and Russia. The analysis of the present study is based on a structural multivariate model formulated for Finn ish sawnwood exports to the UK. The model consists of an export demand equation and a markup price equation. In earlier studies simul taneous multivariate models have not been ap plied in analyzing pass-through in forest prod ucts markets and they have rarely been applied in other commodities markets (see however Rockerbie 1992, Menon 1993 a, 1993b, Kong sted 1996). Previously used models have usually been bivariate, with a price variable being re gressed on an exchange rate (e.g. Knetter 1989, Hänninen Exchange Rate Changes and the Finnish Sawnwood Demand and Price in the UK Market 63 1993, Pick and Park 1991, Uusivuori and Buon giorno 1991). Multivariate approaches based on the markup concept have also been applied, but these appli cations have been single equation models (e.g. Dornbusch 1987, Hooper and Mann 1989, Athu kolara 1991, Athukolara and Menon 1994, 1995, Hung et al. 1993). The present study uses the Johansen (Johansen 1988, Johansen and Juselius 1990 and 1992) multivariate cointegration meth od for nonstationary data for estimation purpos es. This allows for the estimation of a model system, unlike the traditional Engle and Granger (1987) procedure. The findings indicate that PT is large, which means that in the long-run changes in the ex change rate (FIM/pound sterling) are almost com pletely reflected in Finnish prices as measured in pounds. Thus, for example, depreciations and devaluations of the FIM have improved Finnish competitiveness and market share by lowering the relative Finnish price in the UK market. 2 Model In the present study, a theoretical model is formed to describe Finnish sawnwood exports to the UK. The model includes a demand equation and a price equation. An estimate for the exchange rate pass-through (PT) is obtained from the price equation. The same type of model construction has earlier been applied by Kongsted (1996) in modeling Danish manufacturing exports. The model is constructed on the assumption that competition between supplier countries is imperfect in UK sawnwood imports. Thus, the elasticity of substitution model describing de mand for goods from different origins is used to describe the export demand for Finnish sawn wood. The derivation of the export demand as sumes a two-stage optimization of a representa tive sawnwood importer in the UK. First, costs are minimized subject to the expenditure on a good (e.g. sawnwood) and, secondly, this ex penditure is allocated optimally between the prod ucts from different countries of origin. Thus, the export demand for Finnish sawnwood can be represented as where Xf and Pf are the Finnish quantity (1000 m 3) and nominal unit price of sawnwood exports (FIM/m3 ) to the UK market, X a and P 0 are the respective quantity and price (£/m 3 ) of competi tors' sawnwood, ER is the nominal exchange rate (FIM/£), bf is a constant and rj is the elastic ity of substitution (assumed to be constant). Af ter logarithmic transformation of the variables in (1), the export demand relation becomes where lower-case letters denote logarithmic val ues of the corresponding upper-case letters in equation (1), c is a constant term and £ is a disturbance term. The symbol rj is the price elas ticity of demand and equation (2) is homoge nous of degree zero in the nominal variables. In this elasticity of substitution model (2), the change in the relative quantities demanded is assumed to be proportional to the change in the relative price of exports. An equation for Finnish sawnwood price is based on a markup model that has earlier been applied in the estimation of pass-through e.g. by Dornbusch (1987), Hooper and Mann (1989), Athukolara (1991), Athukolara and Menon (1995), Hung et al. (1993). In deriving the price equation, it is assumed that a representative Finn ish exporter firm produces exclusively for an imperfectly competitive UK market, employs constant-returns-to-scale technology and unit pro duction cost, Cf. The firm maximizes profit by taking the competitors' price and the supply of competitors' sawnwood as given and by setting the price in FIM, Pf, as a constant markup over unit production costs, Cf. With Xf denoting ex port quantity, the exporter's profit, Vf, is defined as Profit maximization yields where rj is the price elasticity of demand. Ac cording to Hung et al. (1993), a more general Xf = bfi X„ (PfIP O ER)i (1) */= ~t] (Pf-Po ~ er) + x 0 + c + £ (2) Vf={Pf-CfiXf (3) Pf- (r\-\) (4) Silvo Fennica 32(1) research articles 64 case, in which competitors' prices determine the exporter's price, can be presented by using the concept of a variable markup. Then, a variable markup can be defined by assuming that the coefficient T) depends partly on price competi tiveness in the export market. Competitiveness can be described as the relative price (P„ ER)/Pf, where (P„ ER) is the competitors' price in the terms of exporter's currency (ER = FIM/£). Thus, the price elasticity of demand is From (4) and (5), the pricing behavior of a profit maximizing exporter can be described as a vari able markup over the unit cost: The variable markup, 0, depends on the relative price and may be approximated as where 0 (> 0) is the relative price elasticity of the markup. The constant markup is obtained if 0 = 0 and . Substituting (7) into (6) and taking a logarithmic transformation, a rela tion for the price of Finnish sawnwood in the UK market is obtained: where 7= 1/(1 + 0), 0 < y< 1, <5 = ln07(l + 0) is a constant, and u is a disturbance term that cap tures all other factors. The other symbols are the same as above. Lower-case variables denote logs of the corresponding upper-case variables. The export price, pj, is homogenous of degree zero in the exchange rate and competitors' prices, and the equality restriction is imposed on the coeffi cients of p 0 and er in the estimation. The degree of exchange rate pass-through (PT) can be derived as the absolute value of the ex change rate elasticity of export price measured in foreign currency (e.g. Kongsted 1996). From equation (8) we obtain If 7= 0, then the exchange rate affects the Finn ish price in FIM (equation 8) and thus the chang es in er (FIM/£) are absorbed by the variable markup. This means that Finnish exporters do not pass through changes in the exchange rate to their export prices in pounds, i.e. PT = 0, which indicates perfect competition and the existence of the law of one price in the market. If 7= 1, Finnish export prices in FIM, pj, are proportional to production costs, c/, and PT = 1. This indicates that Finnish exporters fully pass through er changes to their export prices in pounds and keep the markup constant. This indi cates imperfect competition in the market. Be tween the above extremes (oD, + t=1,...,T (10) Trace (r) = -T £/«(l-X.;) (11) i=r+ l P = H(p or n = acp'H' (12) Hänninen Exchange Rate Changes and the Finnish Sawnwood Demand and Price in the UK Market 67 tify the economic long-run relation as being that represented in equations (2) and (8). The testable null hypothesis for exclusion of a variable was Pij =O. Homogeneity between Finnish export price, pf, and the other nominal variables was tested by restricting the respective coefficients accordingly. Finally, the markup relationship was tested by examining if the coefficient of C/ could be restricted to unity. 4 Results 4.1 Cointegration of the Empirical Variables The cointegration estimation was based on the VAR(4) model given by equation (10), with six equations (p = 6) for the period 1978-1994. The lag length, k, of the VAR model was determined by the Schwarz (SC) and Hannan-Quinn (HQ) information criteria, using likelihood ratio tests. Starting from k = 5 (see Doornik and Hendry 1994, p. 287), a reduction of the VAR from k = 5 to k = 4 was accepted. Because the reduction from k = 4 to k = 3 was rejected, k = 4 was used for further modeling. The diagnostic tests on the residuals of the VAR(4) model are presented in Table 1, and they support the model with k = 4. Autocorrela tion of the residuals was examined using the F form of the Lagrange Multiplier (LM) test, which is valid for systems with lagged dependent vari ables. The null hypothesis of no serial autocorre lation was accepted at the 5 percent level. Heter oskedasticity was tested using the F-form of the LM test against 4th order autoregressive condi tional heteroskedasticity. The null hypothesis of no heteroskedasticity was accepted at the 5 per cent level. Normality of the residuals was tested by means of the Doornik-Hansen test (Doornik and Hendry 1994) and the null hypothesis of normality was accepted for all the equations. Also the corresponding vector tests for the equa tion system accepted normality and indicated no autocorrelation. For further details and referenc es concerning these tests, see Doornik and Hen dry (1994). The results of the cointegration estimation of the VAR(4) model indicate that r = 2 (Table 2). According to Johansen's trace test, the hypothe ses of r = 0 and r < 1 can be rejected. Thus two cointegration vectors are accepted at the 5 per cent level. The eigenvectors (Pj) and their weights (otj) obtained from the cointegration estimation of model (10) are shown in Table 3. Of the six eigenvectors, the first two relations ((3i and p 2) are most highly correlated with the stationary part of the process Axt corrected for the lagged values of the differences. Thus, Pi and P2 are the two cointegration vectors determined by the mod el (Johansen 1995). They are normalized by the coefficients of Finnish export quantity, Xf, and Finnish export price, pf The normalized vectors of loadings, otj, are Toble 1. Misspecification tests for the residuals of the VAR(4) model. Equation Autocorrelation Far (4,32) Tests for the residuals and the standard errors Heteroskedasticity Normality Standard errors Farch (4,28) X 2 N(2) of sawnwood exports to the UK and x„ and pa are the respective quantity and price (£/m 3) of competitors' sawnwood. er is the exchange rate (FIM/£) and Cf is the unit cost of Finnish sawnwood output. The first cointegration vector, P, (equation 13), was identified, as was equation (2), by excluding Finnish production cost (9) from the relation and Table 3. Normalized eigenvectors, βj, with correspond ing weights, αj, obtained from the unrestricted cointegration estimation. assuming that the coefficient of is (3ei =-1 ■ The exclusion of c/was accomplished by restricting its long-run coefficient, p4 |, to zero. The second cointegration relation, p2 (equation 14), was iden tified, as was equation (8), by excluding Finland's and the competitors' quantity. When the above restrictions and the homoge neity assumption required by economic theory were tested for the demand and price relations, the test rejected this structure (structure I in Ta ble 4). The homogeneity of the equations in the nominal variables pj., (p„ + er) implies that the coefficients of pa and er should be equal and that the coefficient of cs should equal the differ ence between the coefficients of ps and er in the cointegration vectors. However, the coefficients of the unrestricted equation (13) in particular indicate that homogeneity does not necessarily hold. Thus testing was continued by applying structure II (Table 4), where the homogeneity restriction is applied only in the price equation. The structural form (II) is accepted. The type of demand equation (1) applied in the present P,: 1 .OOxf- 6.15pf- 4A9er + 8.90cy-0.89 />„-2.3(k0 and (13) P 2: o.44xf+\.oopf+o.s7er-0.72cf - 1.26 p„ + 0.50 a„ (14) Null hypothesis Eigenvalues X trace statistics 95% critical values H0:rSi Xi T(i) C(i) r= 0 .56 122.9 * 94.20 r< 1 .36 70.83 * 68.50 r<2 .29 42.23 47.20 r< 3 .22 20.69 29.70 r< 4 .06 4.88 15.40 r< 5 .02 1.18 3.80 Note: * indicate rejection of the null hypotheses implying that the rank is 2. Variables Eigenvectors p. P2 PJ P4 Ps P& x f 1.00 0.44 -0.03 0.83 -0.41 —0.81 Pf -6.75 1.00 -0.48 1.50 -0.82 —0.25 e r -4.49 0.57 1.00 -2.35 0.97 2.29 C1 8.90 -0.72 0.26 1.00 -0.22 0.21 Po -0.89 -1.26 0.38 -2.16 1.00 -0.32 Xo -2.30 0.50 0.27 -1.15 0.06 1.00 Variables Weights ai «2 <*3 0<4 as Ob xf -0.05 -0.09 -0.29 0.26 0.24 0.11 Pf 0.05 -0.03 0.16 -0.17 -0.10 0.01 Cr -0.01 -0.02 -0.52 -0.06 -0.03 0.01 C f -o.oi 0.04 0.05 -0.02 -0.01 0.00 Po -0.04 -0.04 0.57 0.14 -0.11 0.03 XQ 0.16 0.15 0.10 0.32 0.06 0.05 Symbols: x/= Finnish quantity, p/= Finnish price (FIM), er= ex- change rate (FIM/£), c/= Finnish unit cost, p<} = competi- tors' price in pounds sterling and x„ = competitors' quanti- ty- Hänninen Exchange Rote Changes and the Finnish Sawnwood Demand and Price in the UK Market 69 Table 4. Tests for the restrictions on the unrestricted cointegration vectors β1 and β2 under r = 2. Notes: 1) Symbols: x/ = Finnish quantity, p/ = Finnish price (FIM), er = exchange rate (FIM/£), cf - Finnish unit cost, Po = competitors' price in pounds sterling and x 0 = competitors' quantity. 2) * indicates rejection of the restricted model structure. study is not often tested for homogeneity in ear lier applications. The homogeneity condition has usually been satisfied simply by expressing the exporter's and competitors' prices in a common currency in the form PFIPO. Because the price relation fulfills the restrictions and produces the PT estimate, the estimation is continued by re stricting it further. In the accepted structure (II), the price relation p 2 resembles the markup pricing relation with 7= 1 (Table 4). The coefficient of unit cost, cf, is close to unity (-0.92), while the coefficients of the exchange rate (er) and competitors' price (p0 ) are close to zero. Finally, the markup as sumption was tested by restricting the price rela tion accordingly. The resulting structure (III) is also accepted by the test and the final long-run equilibrium relations can be presented as where the symbols are the same as above. Be cause the demand equation failed the homogene ity test, interpretation of its coefficients is prob lematic. However, the signs of the own-price and exchange rate elasticities of Finnish sawn wood export demand are consistent with the eco nomic theory. Moreover, the magnitude of the price elasticity (-2.44) is between the earlier estimated results of Hänninen 1994 (-1.71, esti mated from annual data, 1976-90) and of Tervo et ai. 1988 (-3.1, estimated with Aimon polyno mials, 1-12 lags from quarterly data, 1966-85). The relatively large elasticity of the exchange rate (6.56) implies a large effect of exchange rate on Finnish sawnwood exports to the UK. The restricted price relation (16) representing markup pricing, with y= 1, indicates that Finn ish sawnwood export price in FIM is proportion ate to production cost and the effect of the ex change rate on the FIM price is very small (zero). Thus, exchange rate pass-through is large. A large pass-through coefficient indicates that ex change rate changes are reflected almost pro rata in the Finnish export price in pounds sterling. 5 Conclusions The study examined the long-run exchange rate pass-through (PT) for the Finnish price of sawn wood in the UK market by estimating a demand and price equation system. The data were quar terly and covered the years 1978-1994. Jo hansen's cointegration method, which is suitable for analyzing nonstationary data, was used in the p'i: I.ooxf= -2.44 pf+ 6.56(er + p0 ) + 1.00;t o and (15) P'2: I.oop/= + 0.00(er + p0) + I.ooc/ (16) Variables/ Restricted and normalized demand (fin) and price (Bj2) relations (i = 1 6; j = 1,2) LR-tests (I) (ID (ill) Psj = P3j and P31 = -P21. P31 *-p2l. Mark-up: P42 = 1, P41 =0, Pöl = -1, P12 = 0, P62 = 0, P42 = —O. The constant markup is obtained if 0 = 0 and (j)' = r|/(ri-l). The second equality in (5) derives from the log-linear approximation of the nonlinear function <{>. Substituting (5) into (4) and taking a logarithmic (1) Vf=(Pf-Cf)Xf (2) Pf=Cf Tl/(T1-1) (3) r\=r\((P„ ER)/Pf) (4) Pf =if Cf (5) <|> = <|>((/>0 ER)/Pf) = V((Po ER)/Pf ) 9 6 transformation, a relation for the price of Finnish newsprint (or pulp) in the export market is obtained: where 7 =l/(1+0), 8 is a constant and u is the disturbance term that captures all other possible factors. Symbol 7 (0< 7 < 1) indicates the PT coefficient (PT = -(3 (pf - er)/der) = 7). The other symbols are the same as above. Lower-case variables denote logs of corresponding upper-case variables. The export price, pf; should be homogenous of degree zero in the exchange rate and the competitor's price, and the equality restriction is imposed on the coefficients of pa and er in the estimation. If the coefficient of Finnish cost, 7, is unity in (6), Finnish export price in markkaa (FIM) is determined solely by Finnish production cost. Thus, the markup is held constant after a change in the exchange rate. In this case, the changes in er (FIM/GBP, FIM/DEM), will completely pass through on the Finnish export price denoted in foreign currency and PT=l. If 7 = 0, the changes in er (FIM/GBP, FIM/DEM) are absorbed by the variable markup and PT=O. Thus, export prices in foreign currency do not change (net of any effect exchange rate changes may have on prices through variations in input costs). This indicates perfect competition in the market. Between the two extremes, PT may be incomplete (0< PT t-\,...,T, 9 maximum eigenvalue test and a trace test, from which the trace test results are reported here. Provided that the data series are cointegrated, it may be possible to estimate a cointegration vector the coefficients of which describe the long-run equilibrium relationship implied by equation (6) for each destination country and product. The estimations are based on the VAR model given by equation (7) with four individual equations. The suitable lag length, k, of the VAR model was determined by diagnostic testing of the data in each case. In addition, the Schwarz (SC) and Hannan-Quinn (HQ) information criteria (using likelihood ratio tests for sequential decreases in the number of lags from 5 to 1 in each of the systems) were applied in the determination of the lag length of each of the VAR models (see Doornik and Hendry 1994). When the number of cointegration relations, r, is determined it is possible to test hypotheses on the long-run matrix, IT=aP'. The present study tests restrictions on the coefficients (3y of the cointegration vectors. Homogeneity between Finnish export price, pf, and the other nominal variables, was tested by restricting the respective coefficients accordingly. The markup relationship was also tested by examining if the estimate for 7 (see equation 6) could be restricted as unity in the cointegration vector. Before proceeding with cointegration estimation, the individual time series were tested for nonstationarity using Augmented Dickey Fuller tests (Dickey and Fuller 1979). 3 Test results in Table 1 indicate that all the time series are nonstationary and integrated of order one. The cointegration approach is thus suitable for modelling the long-run exchange rate PT in British and German markets of pulp and paper. 4 3 Also Phillips-Perron (Phillips and Perron 1988) modification of the unit root tests were performed. As the results were found to be uniform regarding the null hypothesis of nonstationarity, the results are not presented here (available from authors upon request). 4 The VAR-models were tested for stability by using Chow-tests and examining the recursive residuals of the four models systems. According to the resulting recursive constancy statistics, there were no problems with the stability of the models. Regarding the cointegrating relationships, also their stability was examined with plotting recursive eigenvalues of individual long run vectors. No signs of instability was detected here either. 10 Exchange rate effects in Finnish newsprint prices Results for Johansen's cointegration rank test for newsprint price model of the UK market are presented in Table 2. The VAR model with seasonal dummies, restricted constant and two lags was found to be sufficient to remove residual autocorrelation of individual equations (diagnostic test results are presented in Appendix 1A). The cointegration rank was found to be one using the trace test with and without the degrees of freedom correction. Also in the German data, a VAR model with seasonal dummies, restricted constant and two lags was found to be a sufficient description of the data generating process (see Appendix 1 A). According to the cointegration rank test (Table 2), the test value for r = 0 is only slightly lower than the critical value, so we can reject r = 0 and accept r = 1. Economic theory requires homogeneity of prices following equation (6). The homogeneity in nominal variables pf, cf and (p0 + er) implies that the coefficients of pa and er should be equal and that the coefficient of cf should equal the difference between the coefficients of pf and er in the cointegration vector. This assumption was tested by restricting the coefficients of the UK and German cointegration vectors accordingly. Long run price homogeneity could be accepted (Table 3) and the restricted cointegrating vectors can be written as where pf is Finnish price (FIM/tn), er is exchange rate, cf is Finnish production cost and p0 is competitors' price (GBP/tn, DEM/tn). The relation (8) indicates that from a 10 percent change of the exchange rate, 6 percent would in the long run be reflected in the Finnish export price in pounds sterling and 4 percent in the markup over domestic costs. If the exchange rate changes were fully reflected in GBP prices, PT would be complete and prices in FIM would remain unchanged. This hypothesis was also tested, but the restriction in the long-run newsprint price relation could not be accepted in the UK (Table 3). For Germany the relationship (9) indicates that in the long-run equilibrium less than one half of an exchange rate change is reflected in DEM and over a half in FIM prices. Consequently, the (8) UK: (3': 1.00/?/= + o.4o(er+po) + 0.60 c/ + 1.85, (9) Germany: p' : 1.00/?/= + o.s4(er+p o) + 0.46 c/ + 1.32, 11 markup assumption, i.e. the restriction of production cost coefficient (7 from equation 6) to one (Table 3) could not be accepted for Germany either. Exchange rate effects in Finnish pulp prices For the pulp price model of the UK, the VAR model with seasonal dummies, restricted constant and four lags was found to be a sufficient description of data generating process (see Appendix IB). Johansen's cointegration rank test in Table 4 indicate the cointegrating rank to be one (at 1 % level) or two (at 5 % level). However, since the degrees of freedom corrected trace test (not reported here) indicated only one cointegrating vector, we proceed according to the theoretical model and identify the pass-through coefficient through imposing price homogeneity in the UK cointegration vector (Table 5). Also in the German data, a VAR model with four lags, seasonal dummies and restricted constant was found to be a sufficient description of the data generating process (see Appendix IB). According to the cointegration rank test (Table 4), the trace test result for r< 2 is above the critical value at 5 % level. However, when using the degrees of freedom corrected version of this test (not reported), the result r=l is obtained. We proceed accordingly and make the coefficient restrictions under rank r=l also on the German cointegrating vector. The markup pricing relations in both countries can be written as where the symbols are the same as above. In the UK cointegrating vector the homogeneity restriction was accepted and the coefficient for long run exchange rate pass-through of 0.07 is obtained for the pulp price (Table 5). Even the zero restriction for the PT coefficient could be imposed for pulp price in the UK, indicating that the Finnish exports of pulp have been insensitive to exchange rate changes. Instead, the restriction of markup relation to express complete pass through (i.e. PT=l) is rejected in the UK data. For Germany, the likelihood ratio test statistic for the restricted price relationship was rather close to 5 % critical value, so we imposed the restriction. According to (11) close to (10) UK: P' : I.oop/= +O.93(er+/>0) + 0.07c/ + 0.18 (11) Germany: p': I.oopf= +o.32(er+p o) + 0.68 c/ + 2.25, 12 70 % of an exchange rate change in the German market was thus reflected in DEM prices and over 30 % in prices denoted in FIM in the long-run equilibrium. Consequently, the markup assumption, i.e. the restriction of production cost coefficient to one (Table 5) could not be accepted for German pulp price. If the magnitude of PT coefficient is interpreted in terms of market competition, the low (even zero) value of it reflects that the UK pulp market is more competitive than German market. V. CONCLUDING REMARKS This paper examines the long-run exchange rate pass-through (PT) of Finnish pulp and newsprint export prices in the UK and Germany. According to the estimation results, pass through effects have been incomplete for both product groups and markets. Thus, changes in the exchange rates are partly reflected in Finnish pulp and paper export prices in foreign currency and partly in the markup over production costs. For newsprint, the elasticity estimates were relatively close to each other in both destination countries (in the range 0.46-0.60), while for pulp, the UK elasticity (0.07) was small as compared to Germany (0.68). The estimated PT coefficients indicate that devaluations have boosted Finnish export demand of paper in the UK and German markets, and that the competition between Finland and the other exporters in these markets has been imperfect. Moreover, Finnish paper exporters appear to have pursued a midway pricing strategy aimed at maintaining market shares and profitability as the exchange rate changes (see also Athukorala and Menon 1995). In contrast, the pricing of Finnish pulp exports has been more clearly destination specific as compared to paper. The results of this study agree with Vesala (1992), whose PT estimate for Finnish paper exports to Europe was 0.66. For newsprint, the present study estimated a slightly lower PT coefficient in Germany than in the UK, which may be related to the smaller market share in Germany than in the UK. Germany is also a large newsprint producer, whose domestic producers may have market power in relation to the foreign importers. One of the underlying reasons for incomplete PT in the UK and Germany may be the location of Finnish paper production capacity in these countries. According to Gron and Swenson 13 (1996), firms' export prices are unlikely to change one-for-one with exchange rate movements if they have production capacity across borders. This may also have affected the magnitudes of the PT estimates for pulp, which seem not be connected with Finnish market shares in the same way as those of the newsprint. Other things related to, for example, the use of pulp as a rawmaterial of paper and a possibility to transfer pricing of pulp in the paper mills owned by Finnish forest industry in the customer countries may have effects on the PT estimates of pulp. The implication of this study for Finland's participation in stage three of EMU is that some adjustment difficulties could arise in pulp and paper industry, because the exchange rate between the Finnish markka and the main importing countries' currencies have affected exports. Along with euro, Finland and Germany will have a common currency, while with respect to the UK the exchange rate will be determined between euro and GBP. Basing on the PT elasticities the effects of EMU membership on the competition for market share are, however, likely to be smaller in Finnish pulp and paper industry than in Finnish sawnwood industry. When Finland joins the EMU, national exchange rate policy can no longer be used to improve Finnish price competitiveness. Hence, other means must be found to adjust to future disturbances caused by shocks in demand and world market prices. ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS We thank Kari Heimonen, Jari Kuuluvainen, Juuso Vataja and an anonymous referee for helpful comments on the earlier versions of this paper. 14 REFERENCES Alavapati, J.R.R., Adamowicz, W.L. and Luckert, M.K. (1997) A cointegration analysis of Canadian wood pulp prices. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 79, 975- 896. Athukolara, P. (1991) Exchange rate pass-through: The case of Korean exports of manufacturers. Economic letters, 35, 79-84. Athukolara, P. and Menon, J. (1994) Pricing to market behavior and exchange rate pass through in Japanese exports. Economic Journal, 104, 271-81. Athukolara, P. and Menon, J. (1995) Exchange rates and strategic pricing: The case of Swedish machinery exports. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 57, 533- 545. The Board of Customs. Foreign Trade. 1980-1994. Helsinki CSO, Overseas Trade Statistics of the United Kingdom. 1980-1994. London. Dickey, D. and Fuller, W.A. (1979) Distribution of the estimators for autoregressive time series with a unit root. Journal of American Statistical Association, 74, 427-431. Doornik, J.A. and Hendry, D.F. (1994) PcFiml 8.0. Interactive Econometric Modeling of Dynamic Systems. Institute of Economics and Statistics, University of Oxford. International Thomson Publishing, London. 436 p. Dornbusch, R. (1987) Exchange rates and prices. The American Economic Review, 77, 92- 106. Engle, R.F. and Granger, C.W.J. (1987) Co-integration and error correction: representation, estimation and testing. Econometrica, 55, 251-176. Feenstra, R.C., Gagnon, J.E. and Knetter, M.M. (1996) Market share and exchange rate pass-through in world automobile trade. Journal of International Economics, 40, 187-207. Gron, A. and Swensson, D.L. (1996) Incomplete exchange-rate pass-through and imperfect competition: The effect of local production. The American Economic Review, 86, 71- 76. Hooper, P. and Mann, C.L. (1989) Exchange rate pass-through in the 1980 s: The case of U.S. imports of manufactures. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1, 297-337. 15 Hung, W., Kim, Y. and Ohno, K. (1993) Pricing exports: a cross-country study. Journal of International Money and Finance, 12, 3-28. Hänninen, R. (1998) Exchange rate changes and the Finnish sawnwood demand and price in the UK market. Silva Fennica, 32, 61-73. Johansen, S. (1988) Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 12, 231-254. Johansen, S. (1995) Likelihood-based inference in cointegrated vector autoregressive models. Oxford University Press Incorporated, New York. 267 p. Johansen, S. and Juselius, K. (1990) Maximum likelihood estimation and inference on cointegration - with applications to the demand for money. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 52, 169-210. Johansen, S. and Juselius, K. (1992) Structural tests in a multivariate cointegration analysis of the PPP and the UIP for UK. Journal of Econometrics, 53, 211 -244. Khosla, A. and Teranishi, J. (1989) Exchange rate pass-through in export prices - an international comparison. Hitotsubashi Journal of Economics, 30, 31- 48. Knetter, M.M. (1989) Price discrimination by U.S. and German exporters. The American Economic Review, 79, 198-210. Knetter, M.M. (1993) International comparisons of pricing to market behavior. The American Economic Review, 83, 473-486. Kreinin, M.E. (1977) The effect of exchange rate changes on the prices and volume of foreign trade. IMF Staff Papers, 47, 207-229. Krugman, P.R. (1987) Pricing to market when the exchange rate changes. In Real-financial linkages among open economies (Ed.) Sven W. Arndt and J. David Richardson, MIT Press, Cambridge, pp. 49-70. Kuismanen, M. (1995) Exchange rates and import prices in Finland: estimation of exchange rate pass-through. Bank of Finland Discussion Papers 17. 33 p. McCarl, 8.A., and Haynes, R.W. (1985) Exchange rate influence on softwood lumber trade. Journal of Forestry, 83, 368-370. Menon, J. (1993) Exchange rate pass-through elasticities for the Monash Model: A disaggregated analysis of Australian manufactured imports. Centre of Policy Studies, Monash University. Working Paper OP-76, July. 51 p. Menon, J. (1995) Exchange rate pass-through. Journal of Economic Surveys, 9, 197-231. 16 Naug, B. and Nymoen, R. (1996) Pricing to market in a small open economy. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 98, 329-350. Phillips, P.C.B. and Perron, P. (1988) Testing for unit root in time series regression. Biometrika, 75, 335-346. Pick, D.H. and Park, T.A. (1991) The competitive structure of U.S. agricultural exports. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 73, 133-141. Rockerbie, D.W. (1992) Exchange rates, pass-through and Canadian export competitiveness: an analysis using vector autoregressions. Applied Economics, 24, 627-634. Spitaeller, E. (1980) Short-run effects of exhange rate changes on the terms of trade and trade balance. IMF Staff Papers, 27, 320-48. Statistisches Bundesamt, Aussenhandel Nach Waren und Ländern, 1980-94, Wiesbaden. Statistics Finland, Bulletin of Statistics (SVT), 1980-1995, Helsinki. Uusivuori, J. and Buongiorno, J. (1991) Pass-through of exchange rates on prices of forest product exports from the United States to Europe and Japan. Forest Science, 37, 931-948. Vesala, J. (1992) Incomplete exchange rate pass-through and hysteresis in trade. A survey of recent theories and empirical study of export pricing of Finnish paper manufactures. Bank of Finland Discussion Papers 29. 76 p. 17 Figure. 1A. Nominal CIF - prices of Finnish newsprint and wood pulp in the UK (GBP/tn) and Germany (DEM/tn) with the exchange rates, FIM/GBP and FIM/DEM. Figure. 1B. Markup. Relation between Finnish unit price of exports (FIM/tn) for newsprint and pulp and production price index (1990=100) for paper and pulp industry. 18 19 Table 1. Results for unit root tests. 1 For critical values, see Dickey and Fuller (1979). Note: Constant or constant and trend (T) included in test equation and N= number of lags needed in test equation to remove autocorrelation. *(**) denotes rejection of null hypothesis of nonstationarity at 5 % (1 %) level. Table 2. Results for the cointegration rank test in British and German newsprint models. Level First difference Newsprint: export price from Finland -1.78 (T, N=0) -6.43** Wood pulp: export price from Finland -1.65 (T, N=0) -4.91** Production cost -2.62 (N=0) -AA1** Exchange rate, FIM/GBP -2.34 (N=0) -6.57** Exchange rate, FIM/DEM -1.61 (T, N=0) Newsprint: competitor's price in UK -2.56 (N=0) -8.62** Newsprint: competitor's price in Germany -0.93 (N=l) -6.16** Wood pulp: competitor's price in UK -3.16 (T, N=0) -8.33** Wood pulp: competitor's price in Germany -1.53 (T, N=0) -3.98** United Kingdom Germany H0:r Autocorrelation of the residuals of individual equations and a whole system was examined using the F-form of the Lagrange-Multiplier (LM) test, which is valid for systems with lagged dependent variables. b> Heteroskedasticity was tested using the F-form of the LM test against 4th order autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity. Normality of the residuals of individual equations and a whole system was tested with the Doornik- Hansen test (Doornik and Hendry 1994). For further detail and test references, see Doornik and Hendry (1994). Symbols: the export price from Finland, er is the exchange rate, cj is Finnish production cost and p„ is the competitor's price. Equation Tests for residuals and standard errors Autocorrelation a> Heteroskedasticity b> Normality c> Standard errors F AR(4,40) FARCH(4,36) X 2 (2) Oe UK: Apf 0.16 [0.96] 0.58 [0.68] 1.84 [0.40] 0.02 Aer 0.86 [0.50] 0.16 [0.96] 7.36 [0.03] 0.03 Acf 1.03 [0.40] 0.07 [0.99] 3.23 [0.20] 0.02 Ap„ 1.30 [0.29] 0.05 [0.99] 47.19 [0.00] 0.01 System: VFAr(64,100)= =1.17 [0.24] Vx 2 (8)=39.26 [0.00]* Germany: Apf 0.29 [0.89] 0.64 [0.64] 0.84 [0.65] 0.02 Aer 0.73 [0.58] 2.19 [0.09] 5.23 [0.07] 0.03 Acf 2.53 [0.06] 0.49 [0.74] 3.66 [0.16] 0.02 Ap„ 1.77 [0.15] 5.48 [0.00]* 5.77 [0.06] 0.02 System: vfAR(64 > 1 00 ) = 1 -25 [0.16] V% 2 (8)=1 1.79 [0.17] 23 APPENDIX 1B. Misspecification tests for residuals from Johansen's cointegration estimation of British and German pulp models with four lags, seasonal dummies and restricted constant. Notes: Values in square brackets are marginal significance levels and * indicates that the null hypothesis is rejected at the 5 percent level. a> Autocorrelation of the residuals of individual equations and a whole system was examined using the F-form of the Lagrange-Multiplier (LM) test, which is valid for systems with lagged dependent variables. Heteroskedasticity was tested using the F-form of the LM test against 4th order autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity. Normality of the residuals of individual equations and a whole system was tested with the Doornik- Hansen test (Doornik and Hendry 1994). For further detail and test references, see Doornik and Hendry (1994). For symbols, see Appendix IA. Equation Tests for residuals and standard errors Autocorrelation a> Heteroskedasticity b> Normality c> Standard errors F AR(4,32) FarCH(4.28) X 2 (2) UK: Apf 0.07 [0.99] 0.88 [0.48] 9.06 [0.01]* 0.07 Aer 3.25 [0.02]* 0.21 [0.93] 3.69 [0.16] 0.03 Acf 1.60 [0.19] 0.38 [0.82] 3.49 [0.17] 0.01 APo 1.38 [0.26] 3.71 [0.02] 39.4 [0.00]* 0.13 System: VFAR (64,68) = 0.97 [0.55] VX 2 (8)=69.34 [0.00]* Germany: Apf 0.13 [0.97] 1.30 [0.29] 3.97 [0.14] 0.06 Aer 0.69 [0.60] 1.15 [0.36] 5.83 [0.05] 0.03 Acf 1.64 [0.18] 0.26 [0.90] 2.73 [0.26] 0.01 Ap<> 2.55 [0.06] 0.35 [0.84] 1.02 [0.60] 0.04 System: VFAR( 64>68)= 1.07 [0.39] VX 2 (8)=22.78 [0.01]* ISBN 951-40-1650-5 ISSN 0358-4283 Hakapaino Oy 1998